Lecture 10: Last updated 01/06/2010

Follow the lecture to revise the notes

Chapter 17

General Equilibrium (Linear Models)

Assume: 2 goods, 2 factors in the economy.

y1,y2: final goods,

x1,x2: factors of production,

p1,p2: prices of final goods (assumed to be fixed by the world market è small country (economy) assumption)

xij = amount of factor i used in industry j.

max

s.t.

for simplification, we can assume that the functions f1 & f2 exhibit constant returns to scale.

for all

let

Input – Output table

I – O coefficients (Technological Coefficients)

L / L1 / L2
K / K1 / K2
Y1 / Y2

so; the constant returns to scale enables us to completely describe the isoquants by the knowledge of one isoquant (unit – isoquant).

Then the model can be written as

Max

s.t.

With fixed technological coefficients , the model becomes a “linear programming model”.

Max

s.t. & &

(here; and

Fixed – Coefficients Production Function

Linear Activity Analysis

Suppose the firm is faced with 3 production coefficient possibilities.

Assumption: the firm can choose any one or more activities simultaneously.

Suppose: 1 unit of output can be produced by ½ of A and ½ of B.

½ of A è ½ of L and 1 of K

½ of B è 3/2 of L and ½ of K

Total è 2 of Labor and 1.5 of Capital è A new combination activity D.

Using the connected line, we get another point E on the same activity line of C but using less of both inputs.

C becomes irrelevant in a cost minimizing problem.

Production is done where slope of isoquant = slope of isocost

·  If , tangency will occur at “A” à relatively more capital intensive activity.

·  If , tangency will occur at “B” à labor intensive activity will be used.

·  If , infinitely many number of solutions along

Algebraic Formulation (Kuhn Tucker can be used) (Minimization Problem)

Min

s.t. &

if A is used (1,2) then,

if B is used (3,1) then,

if c is used (2,3) then,

Problem becomes

Min

s.t

Foc.

If

If

If

At the cost minimizing point, the process with minimum MC will be used.

Numerical Example

A firm produces 2 goods, y1 (food) and y2 (clothing). 3 inputs are land (H), Labor (L) and capital (K). inputs are combined in fixed proportions to produce 1 unit of output.

1 unit of food requires 3 ac/land, 2 w/h, 1 m/h

1 unit of clothing requires 2 ac/land, 2 w/h, 2 m/h

I – O Matrix

Also

F C (food is more land intensive)

Maximize Output

Max

s. t. “ A linear programming model”

Slope of the obj function : 40/30 = 1.333

Comparing the slopes, we see that production will be at point C. it is the intersection of Land and Labor and capital is non – binding.

Therefore, simultaneous solutions of (1) & (2) yields

Derivation of Input Prices

Suppose land is 55 (1 increased). The previous solution would yield;

ð  value of output increased by $10.

VMPLand = 10 = Price of Land in competitive market.

“Shadow Price” or “Imputed rent”

Suppose change in Land: ΔH

similarly by increasing L by ΔL

shadow price of labor.

Finally doing the same for K, we will get

The Rybczynski Theorem

Effects of a change in factor endowment on the output.

Theorem: if the endowment of some resources increases, the industry which uses that resources more intensively will increase its output, value of the other will decrease.

(recall in the example y1 (food) was made land intensive and y2 (clothing) labor intensive).

First industry is land intensive.

Proof of the Theorem

When land increases, output of land intensive industry will increase.

Matrix Format

Cramer’s Rule

for land intensive industry

Rybczynski: (proof)

2. Similarly

For land intensive industry denominator > 0

ECON 603

Chapter 17 continued

Summary

Max

s.t.

With technological coefficients

Problem è Linear programming model

Max

s.t.

Rybz. Theorem

by Cramer’s Rule

Suppose industry 1 is more land – intensive.

Then,

è

Then, for a 1 unit increase in Land (H).

output of y1 which is land intensive good increases.

Also,

in addition for where

then,

è

So, when some factor endowment changes, the output that is intensive in that factor, will change in greater absolute proportion than the parameter.

The Stolper Samuelson Theorem

Effect of an increase in the price of output on the factor prices.

Theorem. If the price of (say) labor intensive good increases, the price of labor will increase and in greater proportion. The price of the other factor falls, (but not necessarily in greater proportion).

Proof: Consider the unit factor cost of y1 and y2. remember we found as a shadow prices of factors.

Here the coefficient matrix is the transpose of technical coefficients matrix of the primal problem.

So the algebra of the relations between the factor and output prices is virtually identical to the relations between physical output and resource endowment.

Solving the system with we get

When

The Dual Problem

Original problem è revenue was maximized constraints were statements of limited resource endowments.

(Primal problem)à shadow factor prices derived.

Recall (envelope theorem)

Lagrance multipliers in primal problem are shadow factor prices.

These are the non-positive profit conditions.

The remaining foc. are the inequality constraints:

For a competitive economy we expect revenue maximization to imply (and to be implied by) “minimization of total value of recourses subject to the constraint that profits are non-positive”. So, Rearranging Lagrange function we get;

A minimization problem w.r.t. and objective function , the total value of recourses.

and,

Primal Problem Dual Problem

Max min

s.t. s.t

obviously, when these two problems are solved, the values of objective functions are identical.

Using the numerical example.

actually, by Euler’s Theorem

The Fundamental Theorem of Linear Programming

General Linear Programming Problem

Primal Dual

Max Min

s.t. s.t.

Theorem: suppose there exists an such that (x0 is the feasible solution) and such that (U0 is the feasible solution of minimum problem).

Then both problems possess an optimal solution (i.e a finate solution) and these two solution values are identical.

Meaning, suppose is the vector that maximizes , such that .

The max value of is

Similarly, let be the vector for which is minimum and . Then .

Simplex Algorithm for Solving Linear Programming Models

Max

s.t.

let be the slack variables, then problem becomes:

Max

s.t. (1)

(2)

Choose as basis. Solve in terms of

(2) & (3) è

(3) è

(1) è

set . This corresponds to point B in the previous diagram.

This is a solution but is it optimal? Does it maximize the objective function?

(if y5 increases, max value increases so that is not optimal because by increasing y5 we can increase z*).

Instead of choosing y5=0, we must increase it but how much?

PAY ATTENTION

For y4=0.

for let y3 be out of the system.

New basis; and write in terms of

(6) and put into (4)

(5)

for

is it optimal?

it is definitely optimum.

Deriving Shadow Prices

Let factor endowments be H, L, K where y3 and y4 are non basis variables.