1

Regime dependence between the official and parallel foreign currency markets for Dollars in Greece

Angelos Kanas

Department of Economics

University of Crete

University Campus

GR-74100

Rethymno, Greece

and

Georgios P. Kouretas*

Department of Economics

University of Crete

University Campus

GR-74100

Rethymno, Greece

May 2003

Abstract

*Corresponding author: email:

1. Introduction

A `parallel` or `black` market for US dollars has operated continuously in Greece since World War II, as a result of the huge government budget deficit and the loans that had to be made to finance the German occupation troops, which eventually led to a 3 year period of sustained hyperinflation (1945-1948) in Greece. Coupled with unstable political and social conditions, this monetary situation led the people to lose confidence in the national currency and most of the transactions were made in US dollars or in gold sovereigns. This situation continued even after the implementation of the major reconstruction plan in the 1950s which had as a distinct feature the devaluation of the drachma by 100 percent against the dollar until very recently when, as a result of Greece’s joining of the European Economic Community, this market ceased to exist in the early 1990s. Although Greece has allowed the Greek drachma to float against major currencies since April 1975, following the collapse of the Bretton-Woods agreement and the establishment of a system of flexible exchange rates in international transactions, the movement to the managed float was accompanied by the imposition of trade and foreign exchange restrictions so that the official exchange rate was not purely market-determined but was still rather administratively determined. Thus, the size of the parallel market was quite considerable with the premium being on average 15%.

2. Theemergence of the Greekblack market for foreign currency

A `parallel` or `black` market for US dollars has operated continuously in Greece since World War II, as a result of the huge government budget deficit and the loans that had to be made to finance the German occupation troops, which eventually led to a 3 year period of sustained hyperinflation (1945-1948) in Greece. Coupled with unstable political and social conditions, this monetary situation led the people to lose confidence in the national currency and most of the transactions were made in US dollars or in gold sovereigns. This situation continued even after the implementation of the major reconstruction plan in the 1950s which had as a distinct feature the devaluation of the drachma by 100 percent against the dollar.

Following the collapse of the Bretton-Woods agreement and the establishment of a system of flexible exchange rates in international transactions, Greece has allowed the Greek drachma to float against major currencies since April 1975. The link to the US dollar was abandoned and a variable trade-weighted system was adopted, where the US dollar had the greatest weight. Greece`s joining of the European Economic Community in 1981 led the Bank of Greece to adjust the trade-weighted system and place a greater weight on the Deutschemark and other European currencies and smaller weight on the dollar. However, the movement to the managed float was accompanied by the imposition of trade and foreign exchange restrictions (Manalis, 1993) so that the official exchange rate was not purely market-determined but was still rather administratively determined. Thus, the parallel market for dollars which developed after World War II was still very much in effect, undermining these restrictions while smuggling of goods was taking place. The two oil price shocks, the chronic high inflation and corresponding current account deficits gave a new momentum to the activities in the parallel market for US dollars during the second half of the 1970s and the first half of the 1980s. By 1984 the size of the market was substantial and, according to the estimates by Pavlopoulos (1987), the annual volume of transactions was approaching 400 million US dollars. Figure 1 shows the evolution of the parallel and official drachma-dollar exchange rates from 1975 to 1993, while Figure 2 shows the evolution of the parallel market premium for the same period. The premium is positive apart from short periods in the second half of the 1980s when it turned to a discount. During that period there were two discrete devaluations of the drachma which were implemented in January 1983 and October 1995 and each one was equal to 15%. The negative premium is explained by the fact that for some periods after 1985 the Bank of Greece forced the commercial banks not to accept foreign currency without proper identification of the source of the foreign currency. In that case the seller was willing to undersell his foreign currency in the black market. In addition, the case of a negative premium after the second devaluation may also be explained by the likelihood that the parallel market agents were expecting a higher percentage of devaluation of the drachma than the realized one, which led to selling dollars at a discount. In January 1986 a liberalization process for capital flows began which was completed in May 1994 when all capital controls on short-term capital were lifted, which led to the virtual elimination of the market by the end of 1993 (Papaioannou and Gatzonas, 1997).

3. Econometric methodology

3.1 The Markov Switching Vector Error Correctionmodel

The Markov Switching Vector Error Correction model(MS-VECM), introduced in Artis et al. (2000) is a multivariate generalisation of the univariate Markov Switching autoregressive (MS-AR) model introduced by Hamilton (1989). The general formulation of the mean-adjusted l-th order MS-AR model,with regime-dependent mean and variance, is

(1)

where yt is a Tx1 vector containing the observations for the single stationary time series {yt}, T is the sample size, μ(st)is the regime-dependent conditional mean, st{1, 2, …, M } is an unobserved regime variable, where M denotes the number of feasible regimes, and ut is the innovation process with a regime-dependent variance-covariance matrix . The unobservable realisation of the regime st{1, 2, …, M} is assumed to be governed by a discrete state Markov process defined by the constant transition probabilities pij:

, , (2)

Anl-th order MS-Vector Error Correction model [MS-VECM(l)] model can be considered as a multivariate generalization of (1). Consider the K-dimensional time series vector Yt= (y1t , …, yKt)’, t = 1, …, T.The MS-VECM(l) model forΔYt is given by

(3)

where A1, …, Al are autoregressive parameter matrices, is the error correction term, and μ(st), Σ(st) are parameter shift functions describing the dependence of the parameters μ andΣ on the regime st, e.g. μ(st) = μ1if st = 1, …, μ(st)= μM if st = M. The MS-VECM(l) is completed by considering the regime-generating Markov process in (2) which allows us to infer the evolution of regimes from the data. It is assumed that st follows an irreducible ergodic M state Markov process with the transition matrix given by matrix P[1]

P = (4)

As the objective of this paper is to model volatility regimes, we focus on a particular version of (3) which allows only for regime-dependent variance (i.e. heteroscedastic error term), while the mean is assumed to be regime-invariant. This model is given in equation (5), and is denoted as the MSH(M)-VECM(l) model:

,

ut ~NID(0, IK) (5)

In this study, we consider the 2-dimensional vector ΔΥt=(Δot, Δpt)′, where Δot denotesthe series of percentage changes of the official exchange rate, and Δpt denotesthe series of percentage change of the parallel currency market. We consider a model with 2 regimes, namely a ‘low’volatility regime (regime 1) and a ‘high’ volatility regime (regime 2).[2] Thus, for the 2-dimensional 2-regime model [MSH(2)-VECM(l)], equation (5) is written as:

,

uo,t ~NID(0, 1).

, (6)

up,t ~NID(0,1)

, ,

where pij are the constant transition probabilities. Maximum likelihood estimation of the model given in (6) is based on the Expectation Maximisation (EM) algorithm discussed in Hamilton (1989), and Krolzig (1997a, 1997b).[3]As a byproduct of the maximum likelihood estimation, Hamilton (1989), shows that several inferences can be drawn.Firstly, one can calculate the unconditional probability that the system will be in regime 1 at any given date. This unconditional probability is given by

(7)

Secondly, a set of conditional probabilities can be obtained, namely the ‘smoothed’ probabilities, representing the ex-post inference about the system being in regime st at date t, based on the entire sample T. For the 2-regime model, the smoothed probabilities at time t are represented by a 1x2 vector, and for the entire sample T, they are represented by a Tx2 matrix. The smoothed probabilities that the system of the two markets is (i.e. the equity market and the Mexican currency market are jointly) in regime 1 and 2 are denoted by,respectively. Thirdly, one could date the regime switches based on the Tx2 matrix of the smoothed probabilities. Assigning dates to regime switches and thus, the classification of regimes, amounts to assigning every observation ΔYt to a given regime. On the basis of the smoothed probability for each date t, we assign that date to a given regime according to the highest smoothed probability. For 2 regimes, the rule is to assign the observation to the first regime if Pr(st = 1 | ΔYT ) > 0.5, and to assign it to the second regime if Pr(st = 1 | ΔYT ) < 0.5. Lastly, the average duration of each regime can be calculated, on the basis of the formula di = (1-pii)-1, i = 1,2, where di is the average duration of regime i.

3.2.Testing forvolatility regime independence

An important advantage of MSH(2)-VECM(l)is that it allows for testing of whether the high volatility regime of the official currency market is independent of the high volatility regime of the parallel market. To formally test the null hypothesis of independence, we estimate a univariate model forthe official marketof the form:

, ut ~NID(0, 1) (8)

In this model, lagged parallel market returns enter as an exogenous explanatory variable in order for the right hand side of this model to be the same as the right hand side of the official market equation in MSH(2)-VECM(l) in (6) and to have the same conditioning set. The model in (8) is called the MSH(2)-ARX(l) model for official currency market. Similarly, for the parallelcurrency market, we estimate an MSH(2)-ARX(l) model in which lagged official market percentage changes enter as an exogenous variable:

,~NID(0, 1). (9)

From the estimation of (8), we obtain the Tx1 vector of the smoothed probabilities that the official market is in the highvolatility regime at time t,. Similarly, from estimating (9), we obtain the Tx1 vector of probabilities that the parallel market is in the high volatility regime at time t,. If the volatility regimes of the two markets are independent, then the probability that the system of the two markets is (i.e. the probability that both markets are jointly)in the high volatility regime () should be equal to the product of the probability that the official market is in the high volatility regime () and the probability that the parallel currency market is in the high volatility regime () at time t. Therefore, the null hypothesis of independence is:

, (10)

with the alternative of dependence being, where denotes the smoothed probabilities that the official market and the parallel market are jointly (i.e. the probabilities that the system of the two markets is) in the high volatility regime.

To test this hypothesis, we obtain the Tx1 vector containing the products of the probability that the official market is in the high volatility regime at time t and the corresponding probability that the parallel market is in the high volatility regime at time t, . Then, we compare this Tx1 vector with the Tx1 vector of the smoothed probabilities . This is a paired data comparison (namely, vsv , vsv , vsv , …, vsv ), and is carried out using the Wilcoxon test.[4] The null hypothesis of this test is that the two series come from the same distribution with the same location, which is equivalent to the independence hypothesis. The alternative hypothesis is that the two series come from two distributions of identical shape but different location, which is equivalent to volatility regime dependence. Our tests are based on both asymptotic and bootstrapped critical values for the Wilcoxon test.[5]

3.2. Regime-dependent impulse responses using the Markov Switching VAR model

An additional means of measuring how the official currency market reacts to disturbances from the parallel market and vice versa is to employ impulse response analysis. We use the estimated Markov Switching VAR models to calculate the response of the official market to a shock in the parallel market, and the response of the parallel to a shock in the official. We seek to explore which market exercises the more persistent impact on the other. Our impulse response functions are regime-dependent; they measure the expected changes in one market at time t+h to a one standard deviation shock to the other marketat time t within each regime.[6]The regime-dependent impulse response function for regime i is defined as follows:

for h≥0 (1)

where h is the time horizon (in months). Estimates of the response vectors can be derived by combining the parameter estimates of the unrestricted Markov switching VAR model in (XX) with the estimate of the matrix (st) obtained through identification restrictions.[7] For exposition purposes, let us assume that we seek to estimate the impulse response of the official exchange rate changes from a shock in the parallel market. A one standard deviation shock to the parallel market implies that the initial disturbance vector is u0(0, 1), i.e. a vector of zeros apart from the 2nd element which is 1. Pre-multiplying this vector by the estimate of the regime-dependent matrix gives the impact responses. The remaining response vectors can be estimated by solving forward for the official exchange rate changes. The following expression shows the solutions linking the estimated response vectors with estimated parameters:

,for h >0 (2)

4. Empirical results

5. Conclusions

References

Table1. Descriptive statistics

Official
Market /

Parallel market

Mean

Standard Deviation

Skewness

Kurtosis

JB

LBS(4)
COINT

Notes:

  1. LBS(4) denotes the Ljung-Box statistic with 4 lags for the squared returns. This is distributed as.
  2. JB denotes the Jarque-Bera normality test. This is distributed as.
  3. COINT denotes the Johansen and Juselius (1990) test for bivariate cointegration between the logarithm of the Mexican exchange rate and the logarithm of each country's equity index. This test was computed on the assumption of a linear deterministic trend in the data. The 5% critical value is 25.32.
  4. * denotes statistical significance at the 5% level.

Table 2. Official and Parallel currency market: MSH(2)-VECM.

Parameters
H0: (No volatility regime switch, homoscedastic VECM(4))
HA: (Volatility regime switch, heteroscedastic MSH(2)-VECM(4))
Likelihood
LR
AIC
HQIC
ae
ae,e,1
ae,e,2
ae,e,3
ae,e,4
ae,c,1
ae,c,2
ae,c,3
ae,c,4
ac
ac,e,1
ac,e,2
ac,e,3
ac,e,4
ac,c,1
ac,c,2
ac,c,3
ac,c,4

(continued overleaf)

(Table 2 continued)

Parameters
SD of equity market: Regime 1
SD of equity market: Regime 2
S.D. of parallel currency market: Regime 1
S.D of official currency market: Regime 2
Correlation coef:
Regime 1
Correlation Coef:
Regime 2.
Unconditional probability:
Regime 1
Unconditional probability: Regime 2
Average Duration:
d1
d2
Regime classification:
High-volatility regime

Notes:

  1. LR denotes the value of the likelihood ratio test for testing the null hypothesis: H0:, namely no volatility regime switch (linear VECM). The values in curly brackets next to the LR statistic are the marginal significance level of this test, based on Davies (1987).
  2. S.D. stands for the standard deviation.
  3. The values in brackets report the respective values from the corresponding linear VECM(4) model.
  4. t-statistics are reported in parentheses.
  5. * denotes statistical significance at the 5% level.

Table 3. Tests for independence between the volatility regime of the official and parallel currency markets

Wilcoxon statistic / Marginal significance level
Bootstrap / Asymptotic

Notes:

  1. The null hypothesis is that of independence in volatility regimes between the official and parallel currency markets. The alternative is that of dependence.
  2. The bootstrapped marginal significance is based on 1000 repetitions. (These experiments were conducted in S-PLUS).
  3. * denotes rejection of the null hypothesis of independence in favour of the alternative of dependence at the 5% level.

[1]A comprehensive discussion of the theory of Markov chains is given by Hamilton (1994).

[2] Allowing for a higher number of regimes, and since we are interested in multivariate estimation, would considerably complicate the estimation. Standard likelihood ratio tests of the null hypothesis of two regimes against the alternative of three regimes cannot be used because the parameters pij are unidentified under the third regime. Precise Hansen (1992) tests are computationally expensive in this case, because of the large number of parameters needed for the grid.

[3] The EM algorithm has been introduced by Dempster et al. (1977) for models where the observed time series depend on an unobservable stochastic variable, i.e. st. Each iteration of the EM algorithm involves two steps. The first step, known as the expectation step, involves the estimation of the unobserved states st by determining their smoothed probabilities. The second step, known as the maximisation step, involves estimating the parameter vector from maximising the likelihood function where the unknown conditional probabilities are replaced with the smoothed probabilities obtained from the first step. Having obtained the parameter vector, the filtered and the smoothed probabilities are updated and so on, guaranteeing an increase in the value of the likelihood function at each step.

[4]Unlike the two-sampled t-test, the Wilcoxon test does not assume that the observations come from normal (Gaussian) distributions. For an analytical exposition, see Hollander and Wolfe (1973).

[5] The bootstrapped critical values were calculated as follows: From the empirical distribution of , we draw with replacement a bootstrap sample of T observations and calculate the Wilcoxon statistic. We repeat this 1000 times and thus obtain 1000 test statistics. Next, we establish the 5% fractiles of the distribution of these 1000 statistics. The bootstrapped marginal significance level is based on those critical values. The bootstrapped experiments were conducted using S-PLUS.

[6] Ehrmann et al. (2003) argue that regime-dependent impulse response functions can be a useful analytical tool.

[7] See Ehrmann et al. (2003).