A/T SHORT OUTLINE
WHAT CONDUCT IS ILLEGAL
- Central Role for Economic Analysis
- Economic effects: collusion or exclusion – focus on inc. prices, dec. output, loss of innovation
- Substitution/Switching: demand elasticity
- Entry
- Surplus – consumer or producer (most juris favor consumers)
- Collusive Effects – directly impairs mkts by coordinated activity btwn firms w/ mkt power to reduce own output
- Exclusionary Effects – indirectly impair mkts by raising rival costs; single firm or collusive (cause others to reduce their output)
- What factors effect if corporation will comply w/ rules:
- Legal Standards
- Per se
- Evidence of a/c effect not req’d; presumed w/ no excuses allowed.
- Used when have experience w/ the sort of conduct under consid
- Makes most econ sense when: prohib conduct would likely harm competition severely, D will frequently claim conduct is reasonable; little pro-competitve conduct will be deterred
- Rule of Reason, Quick Look – burden shifting, efficiencies.
- Arg for more lenient rule – false positives more costly b/c deters precompetitive conduct and mkt power likely to be temporary
- Arg for less lenient rule – mkt power results in immed harm and is often long-lasting
- ANTITRUST INJURY REQUIREMENT – Brunswick Corp v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat (1977)
- Arose at time of signif econ change – mid-70s see rise of foreign competition
- Injury must be the sort that A/T laws sought to regulate – protect competition, not competitors
- JTC Petroleum v. Piasa Motor Fuels (7th Cir 1999) – exclusionary group boycott
- 2 level cartel – producers and applicators –A gets P to enforce and to exclude JTC
- Justification a pretext b/c were paying in cash
- Bell Atlantic v. Twombley (2007) – elevated pleading requirement
- Complaint must rise above speculative level – req’s some facts suggesting agreement.
- ANALYSIS STEPS
- Step 1 – concerted or exclusionary action
- Step 2 – type of restraint/theory of anticompetitive harm
- Step 3 – determine the mkt and mkt share allocation.
HORIZONTAL AGREEMENTS
- Sherman Act S.1 – 2 elements: “contract, combination, conspiracy” & “restraint of trade”
- Per Se Ban on Price-Fixing
- Trenton Potteries (1927)
- Aim and result of every price fixing is the elimination of 1 form of competition – can have no benefit to competition; thus no further analysis is necessary
- “Reasonable” price today may be unreasonable tomorrow
- Appalachian Coal – no monop menace b/c no mkt power – “honest effort to remove abuses”
- US v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co (1940)
- Per se rule clearly established for ALL price-fixing
- Need only to have intent (FN59) – not having mkt power is not a defense
- Horizontal Agreements Subject to Per Se Condemnation
- Price-Fixing – entire price or one term (incl. credit terms)
- Output Restriction
- Market Allocation
- Customer Allocation
- CHARACTERIZATION
- Broadcast Music Inc v. Columbia Broadcasting System (1979)
- Before condemning conduct as per se illegal, need to “characterize” the conduct – implicit in the framework.
- To use per se, need to establish that the conduct is “plainly a/c” and “without redeeming value”
- Here, this is not price-fixing in the literal sense
- Would not expect any mkt arrangement reasonably necessary to effectuate [IP] rights to be deemed per se illegal
- Blanket licenses accompany the integration, sale, monitoring, & enforcement
- Clearing companies add value to the process
- Catalano Inc. v. Target Sales - collective refusal to compete on credit terms indisting from price fixing (refused to deal with beer suppliers on credit; cash only)
- Texaco v. Dagher (2006) – single firms cannot price fix. When firms pool capital and share risks, regarded as a single firm.
- MARKET DIVISION – Per Se Illegal
- Timken – div of mkts by competitors per se violation – group viewed as a cartel and action is an alternative means of price-fixing.
- US v. Topco (1972)
- Classic per se violation is agreement btwn competitors at the same level.
- Justification - need mkt division to compete w/ larger chains.
- Good intention is not a defense.
- No authority to determine respective value of competition in a sector
- Should have made the BMI new product argument (came 9yr later)
- Palmer v. BRG of Georgia (1990) – straight forward geog allocation per se illegal
- HYPO – how would Topco have come out under BMI or Sylvania?
- OUTPUT RESTRICTION – Collusive Boycott(effort to bet higher price from rival)
- FTC v. Superior Court Trial Lawyers Ass’n (1990)
- Constriction of supply to raise price the essence of price-fixing – per se illegal
- Social justifications do not make restraint any less lawful
- Disting from Noerr b/c restraint was consequence of seeking new law
- O’Brien only held that Court should apply A/T law w/ sensitivity to 1st Am concerns
- “No mkt power” is not a cognizable defense
- National Society of Professional Engineers v. US (1978) – Professional Services.
- Sherman Act does not require competitive bidding, but does prohibit unreasonable restraints of trade.
- Preventing competitive bidding illegal under RoR
- Defense (quality would decrease) is not cognizable – impedes ordinary give and take of mkt place by not allowing price negotiations. Not NSPE’s job to determine whether competition is good or bad.
- Impact of NPSE on burdens production/proof
- Per se – only have to prove action is in per se category
- RoR – multi-faceted analysis where P gets to intro more evidence
- Reframed A/T law around core economic issues.
- DEVELOPMENT OF QUICK LOOK FOR HORIZONTAL AGREEMENTS
- Evolution of Unreasonableness
- US v. Trans-Missouri Freight Ass’n (1897) – Every means Every, but did recognize that common law supported some exceptions
- Standard Oil (1911) – reasonableness is intended in S.1
- Addyston Pipe – separated naked and ancillary restraints (per se v. RoR)
- Board of Trade of City of Chicago v. US (1918) – Origins of Rule of Reason
- Must consider facts peculiar to business:
- Condition before and after restraint – could still send bids after close, just temporary restriction on price
- Nature of Restraint – restrained to small amount of daily business
- Effect (actual or probable) – no effect generally on mkt price/volume
- The Quick Look Analysis
- NCAA v Board of Regents FN39 – “RoR can sometimes be applied in the twinkling of an eye”
- Goal is to cut from RoR Analysis where conduct has obvious a/c consequences
- Common Quick Look Test – burden shifting (Law v. NCAA)
- P has initial burden of showing adverse effect – quick review shows harm to competition.
- D then gets to show pro-competitive effects, must be cognizable and supported by evidence.
- P can show that rule not reasonably necessary or can be implemented using less restrictive means
- If met, then balance – generally based on weight of the evidence.
- Board of Regents of University of Oklahoma (1984)
- TV restriction illegal under quick look
- Per se rule not applied b/c of characterization – need some agreement for product to exist
- However, restrictions not linked to the product – removes price competition and decreases quantity.
- Cannot protect weaker product by harming more attractive product – good motives will not validate an otherwise a/c restraint
- Mkt power not essential to proof of illegality – absence of mkt power does not justify restraint
- Cal Dental Ass’n v. FTC (1999)
- Quick Look Analysis not sufficient – need more extensive inquiry.
- Looking at circum, details, logic of restraint, the object is to see whether experience of mkt has been so clear that confident conclusion about principal tendency will follow from the quick look.
- Polygram Holding Inc v. FTC (DC Cir 2005)
- Use Quick Look, not per se b/c might be certain way to limit own venture to benefit common undertaking, but still see as dangerous.
- In determ whether competition restrained, inquiry must be met for the case
- JV inherently suspect, due to close resemblance to suspect practices.
- Case seems to expand QL to where there may not be actual evidence of a/c effects, but only a high likelihood.
- TEST
- Commision determ whether it is obvious that consumers will likely be harmed (“inherently suspect” – consid earlier cases and econ theory
- If “inherently suspect” D must come forward w/ justifications
- Submit fuller evidence of harm
- Commission must then address in 1 of 2 ways:
- Confidently conclude that consumers likely harmed
- Provide suffic evidence to show a/c effects likely.
- D must show actual pro-competitive effects or that benefits outweigh harms.
- Non-Cognizable Defenses for Horizontal Restrictions
- Competition reasonable/destructive (NSPE)
- Prices set were reasonable (SCTLA)
- No market power (NCAA & SCTLA)
- Restraint protected weaker product from stronger product (NCAA)
- DETERMINING WHAT IS CONCERTED ACTION
- Economics of Modern Cartels – what they have to do to succeed
- Reach consensus
- Deter and punish cheating
- Cope w/ new or external threats – mavericks/hold-outs; new entry/subs; suppliers; buyer resistance.
- Certain factors make collusion more or les likely
- # of firms
- Product heterogeneity
- Excess capacity (yours or others)
- Predictable Demand
- Lumpy Sales/Large Buyers
- Info Sharing
- Mere sharing NOT ILLEGAL, nor is agreement to share
- Considered a plus factor
- Eval’d through rule of reason: common themes:
- Legitimacy of sharing and decreased risk if smaller mkt share
- Better off if info is aggregated
- More likely to be acceptable if data is past info
- If “benchmark” info, have 3d party do it w/ a template
- American Column & Lumber (1921)
- 90% of members, extensive and detailed data, incl. name of buyer, seller and price; also suggested prices and production levels; not made available to buyers
- HELD as a conspiracy to fix prices – could be understood as helping firms to reach consensus and deter cheating.
- Maple Flooring (1925)
- 22 members, 70% of US production.
- HELD to have competitively legitimate purposes
- Disting from AC&L b/c didn’t ID buyer/seller, didn’t share current prices or make recommendations.
- Parent & Sub – Copperweld Corp v. Independence Tube Corp (1984)
- Parent and wholly-owned sub considered one entity, thus no S.1 scrutiny
- Decision w/in a corporation to implement single firm’s policy – common purpose and should be able to choose own corp org structure
- Holding been expanded to: parents and less than wholly owned subs; sister corps; other intra-enterprise conduct
- Incomplete Coordination – In re Brand Name Prescrip Drug Litigation (7th Cir 1997)
- Denied pharmacies discounts, but retained discounts for “preferred buyers”
- Cartel may not be tight enough to prevent large, bulk buyers from shifting demand
- Single price may not always be profit maxizing
- Thin profits don’t disprove cartel – could have been thinner
- Matsushita’s “no economic sense” test unavailing.
- Oligopolistic Interdependence – is it concerted action?
- Posner – YES, in some circum: equiv to negotiation, eventually get a pegged $
- Turner – NO, it’s a natural thing for firms to do.
- INFERRING CONSPIRACY
- Interstate Circuit v. US (1939)
- Distrib knew others also being approached and plan would only work w/ concerted action.
- This constituted an AGREEMENT.
- Unanimity of Action – enough that concerted action was invited and contemplated and that they participated.
- Failed to provide contrary testimony – seen as estab the weakness of any counter-testimony.
- American Tobacco v. US (1946)
- Similar, subsequent actions of competitors can support finding of conspiracy
- No formal agreement is necessary – can be found in course of dealing
- Important Factors: concentrated oligopoly (community of interest), parallel conduct, falling cost and declining demand (yet $ increasing) – combo’d show firms knew what they were doing
- Parallelism Plus Doctrine – Theater Enterprises Inc v. Paramount (1954)
- Circumstantial evidence of consciously parallel behavior may have made strong inroads, BUT
- It has not read “conspiracy” out of the Sherman Act entirely.
- Current Doctrine
- Circum proof can estab conspiracy, but…
- Proof of parallel conduct alone not suffic to estab concerted action. Thus,
- Proof of agreement req’s parallel conduct plus other proof.
- Plus Factors (p310-311)
- Industry conditions – structure, product characteristics
- Firm Conduct – irrational behavior, info sharing, other communications
- Past behavior indicating collusion.
- Approaches to plus factors: Check the box; Link to Conspiracy/what cartel has to do to succeed; weigh according to past cartel experience.
- PROVING CONCERTED ACTION
- Invitation to Collude – US v. American Airlines (5th Cir 1984)
- Mere suggestion of collusion can trigger S.2 violation (attempted monop)
- 2 req’d elements – Specific Intent & Dangerous Probability – at time act occur
- Dangerous Probability – call btwn CEOs and high mkt share
- Might have been okay if firms were smaller (threshold: 50%)
- It is not a defense that plan proved impossible to execute.
- Pre-Matsushita – Poller v. CBS (1962) – summary procedures should be used sparingly.
- Monsanto (1984) – build up to Matsushita
- Where illegal action appears same as legal action, P must show more likely than not due to concerted action.
- Matsushita v. Zenith Corp. (1986) – standard for Summary Judgment
- Evidence must “TEND TO EXCLUDE THE POSSIBILITY” that the action was for competitive benefits – “plausibility”
- If evidence ambiguous, P must show more at trial.
- Conduct as consistent w/ permissible competition as w/ illegal conspiracy does not support inference of A/T conspiracy. – circum evid + plausibility.
- Pred Pricing is by its very nature speculative
- To be rational, must have reasonable expectation of recouping
- Also uncertain b/c req’s maintaining mkt power
- Even more difficult when firms have to coordinate
- Makes no “economic sense”
- Three factors helf confer coordinated equilibrium
- Behavior more complex than would be plausible w/o agreement
- Justifications given are weak
- Opportunity for firms to communicate.
- Two Situations where Matsushita “no economic sense” test should shield firms
- Industry structure not conducive to coordination (thus would be irrational)
- Could have been achieved by leader-follower behavior, w/o agreement
- Expanded Emphasis on Procedural Screens
- Matsushita’s “plausibility” screen has been extended backward to the pleading stage
- Twombley (2007)–complaints must rise above speculative level (motion to dismiss)
- “Plausible” is greater than possible – parallel behavior is not enough; req’s some facts suggesting agreement
- Arg – AT&T break-up firms should have been expanding to other mkts; defended by saying it was too risky – no req to compete, but can’t not compete
- In re Text Messaging Antitrust Litigation (7th Cir 2010)
- P must meet “plausibility” standard to survive dismissal of suit
- Used economically grounded approach – looked at what factors make conspiracy more or less probable
- Plus factors supplement communication, hard-to-understand conduct counts
- Direct evidence not essential
- In re Publication Paper Antitrust Litigation (2d Cir 2012)
- P put forth suffic evidence to permit reasonable jury to find that higher prices resulted from agreement rather than independent action
- Range of permissible inference depends on plausibility – broader inferences allowed when theory is more economically sensible.
- Factors
- Structural conditions – commodity prod, few subs, lmt’d #sellers, high barriers to entry
- Counter-intuitive pricing
- Excess capacity (closing mills)
- Parallel pricing
- Direct evidence – “we’re a follower”
DISTRIBUTIVE ARRANGEMENTS
- Distinction btwn substitutes and complements
- Relevant legal framework
- Antitrust law (below)
- State law (eg: dealer location restrictions)
- Sector specific (eg: petroleum market)
- History/Early Cases
- Dr. Miles (1911) – vertical price restraints unlawful – once sold, cannot control price
- Albrecht – extended Dr. Miles to maximum RPM
- Colgate (1919) – weakened Dr. Miles; only applies where there is agreement
- US v. GE (1926) – may set RPM when there is a genuine principal-agent relationship
- Schwinn – per se rule for vertical, intrabrand non-price restraints (territorial)
- Miller Tydings Act (1937) and McGuire Act (1952) – states may auth RPM laws
- Consumer Goods Pricing Act (1975) – repealed Miller-Tydings and McGuire Acts – Dr. Miles now back in full force (has to do w/ econ conditions at the time).
- Monsanto – rasied burden for proving RPM (Cong refused to fund arg for repeal of Dr. Miles)
- Business Electronics Corp (1988) – raises Monsanto standard, harder to prove agreement, on price or price level
- State Oil v. Khan – abandoned per se rule for max RPM
- Vertical Non-Price Restraints – Continental TV Inc v. GTE Sylvania (1977)
- Restriction per se violation under Schwinn, BUT Schwinn should be overturned.
- RoR is the standard, and departure is only justified by demonstrable a/c effect (Northern Pacific)
- These sorts of agreements are not manifestly a/c (“transaction cost literature” – Turner)
- Schwinn did not distinguish actions based on the indiv potential for intrabrand harm or interbrand benefit
- Recognized Justifications for Non-Price Intrabrand Restraints
- Induce competent retailers to carry new products
- Promote existing products
- Defeat mkt imperfections
- Insulate mnfctr from product liability exposure
- Protect mnfctr reputation by ensuring quality.
- Post-Sylvania – P has been successful only when D has interbrand mkt power or there is not evidence of pro-competitive purposes.
- Vertical Price Restraints – Leegin Creative Leather Products v. PSKS Inc (2007)
- Recent (econ) jurisprudence has rejected rationales justifying Dr. Miles’ per se rule
- Cannot be stated w/ confidence RPM always or most always tends to restrict completion and decrease output – per se rule would inc. total cost to system.
- Potential Harms – mnfct cartel; retail cartel; forestall innovation in distribution
- Justifications
- Can stimulate interbrand competition by suppressing intrabrand competitioin.
- Encourage retailers to invest in tangible/intangible services/promos
- Facilitate new mkt entry by inducing competent and aggressive retailers to invest in necessary capital/labor.
- Also allows other pricing programs to be eval’d on their merits
- Vertical v. Horizontal – Characterizing the Challenge – Nynex Corp v. Discon (1988)
- Distribution chain choices are not per se illegal – freedom to switch from one retailer to another
- Distinguish case here from Klor’s b/c this is a vertical chain
- On remand – could still use RoR to estab a/c harm; kickback not an A/T issue.
- Post Leegin Process
- Apply BMI to RPM cases
- Rule of Reason Standard
- Screens – mkt power, cartels (producer or retailer)
- Legal Issues from the Apple e-Book Decision
- Parallelism Plus Doctrine
- Entered same agreement w/ all publishers – resulting in uniform price increases
- Evid of conspiracy can be found through direct evid (Job’s statements) and circum evid (goals, shift in model, simultaneous and sudden price increases) – suffic to infer collective action.
- Apple’s Args:
- Does not “tend to exclude”; however, evid here leaves ambiguity (go to jury)
- Never intended to conspire; however, good motives don’t allow a/c injury
- Distrib relationships in the EU – distinctions from US System
- More particular categories of agreement articulated
- EC can exempt indiv agreements/categories
- Interpreted more broadly than S.1
HORIZONTAL MERGERS