Torts Outline – Professor Turley
- Schools of Thought
- Formalism
- Code system, consisting of canons, case-made, judge-made rules
- Rules are “outcome determinative”; goal- prevent bias/ subjectivity of judges
- Fierce notion of judicial neutrality/deference; court should not engage in determining what law should be rather than what it is; leave lawmaking to legislative branch
- Legal Realism- replaced Formalism in the Torts Revolution
- Rejection of formalism; acceptance of the indeterminacy of the law
- Karl Llewellyn found judges selected canons and pre-determined outcome (hidden bias); false neutrality
- Began policy goal of creating a stable rule; consider broader implications
- consider what reasonable person would have done and the goal of achievement
- Normative
- Goal- determine what is “norm of society”, what is morally right/wrong in society, usually decided by jury
- Hobbes- Leviathan guarantees recourse/ remedy; corrective justice- law must make wrongs right vs. efficiency of CLS (producing most efficient manner of achieving wealth maximization rather than righting of wrongs)
- Lockean
- Labor Theory: In beginning, all was held in common. Then evolved into private property (mixing of sweat/labor = conversion of common property into private property)
- Gvmt does not create priv. property- God created private property;gvmt may not redistribute wealth
- Locke’s Proviso: One must leave “as good and enough for others” (used by Rawls to justify redistribution if extreme concentration of wealth occurs b/c it is defeating God’s plan of allowing man to produce through enterprise)
- Utilitarianism
- gvmt must protect individuals, not just market
- Bentham- goal of gvmt- achieve the greatest good for greatest number; invest in social action tremendous productivity (industrial revolution); gvmt = engineer of society
- Feminism
- Katherine MacKinnon- law written by middle-aged white men- inherent patriarchalbias
- Jurispathic v. jurisgenerative
- Jurispathic- basis of law is combative, male model; lawyer is knight; zero sum game- only one person wins/ gains
- Better Jurisgenerative- judges evaluate merit on both sides and shape an equitable decision
- Bender- should have duty to perform low-cost rescues; Posner agrees, but from an efficiency standpoint
- Critical Legal Studies
- Goal- judges should actively work to break down class barriers; help marginalized
- Sometimes favored judicial activism, courts should be more socially active
- DuncanKennedy- peeled onion of Blackstone’s Commentaries
- Favored de-construction of ‘legal terms’
- Wealth re-distribution is important (Rawls)
- CLS counted by Judicial Restraint
- Goal- deference to the legislature; judges are not elected and are counter-majoritarian
- Madisonian System:
- Tri-part gvmt provides checks balances
- Factions political pressure majority rule (elimination of factions)
- If left to judges- no faction pressure relief, too much control given to individual
- Hart and Sachs- the system works best when courts leave it to legislature to fill gaps/ ambiguous legislation; Courts must stay in line w/the Madisonian system
- But see- Public Choice Movement
- Hart and Sachs view is wrong; gvmt often favors minority opinions rather than majority principles; deals/gaps = Congress making decisions to detriment of public
- Mancur Olson
- disagrees with Madison’s view- collective action: small groups are actually more powerful than big groups b/c small groups have concentrated interest
- vs. majority groups, that have dispersed interests and more free riders
- Easterbrook
- Dealism- gaps in legislation are bought and sold like a market
- Court must apply laws exactly as written; do NOT gap fill: limited judicial role
- Jonathan Macey- agreed w/public choice criticism, but not the result
- DO gap fill; take Congress at its word and enforce the “public-regarding purpose” of legislation; Congress can fix it if wrong
- Madisonian democracy works best when open and deliberative process; this is achieved by filling gaps to public regarding purpose, forcing Congress to amend out in open to continue deal-making
- Hegel
- Personality theory of property- the subjective value of an object to an individual is not recognized by the law- disconnect
- the only way to understand property is to understand its relationship to the person
- Law and Economics School
- Goal- efficiency, not morality
- Posner
- morality is bad basis for law b/c of subjectivity; it’s indeterminate; focus on economic efficiency instead, which is more tangible and will improve the living conditions
- Negligence is the most effective system; strict liability forces cost-internalization, leaving it to the market to dispose of inefficient activities
- 2 most common definitions of EFFICIENCY:
- Pareto Efficiency
- Goal- get a pareto superior result- produces at least one winner and doesn’t make anyone worse off- making things more efficient
- Pareto optimality- point of optimal efficiency; point before first loser is produced
- Kador-Hicks Efficiency
- Goal- wealth maximization; producing losers doesn’t matter as long as there is a net gain; no need to compensate losers
- Externalities
- Rational actors try to externalize their cost to others (i.e. externalizing pollution)
- Hardin’s Tragedy of the commons- wealth maximizing farmers will continue to add cows to shared land w/finite amt. of grass even if doing so will cause the land to stop producing food; result- everyone starves
- Solution? Introduce private property creates incentive to keep resource healthy
- Pigou
- only legislate when the market fails by allowing something contrary to the long-term needs of society
- Examples- stimulus package; force a discriminatory firm off market w/legislation
- CoaseTheorum
- Coase I- in a perfect market, the market determines the outcome of conflicts btw two uses – more valuable resource will ultimately prevail(farmer/ rancher ex.)
- redistribution/regulation not necessary- market will handle it
- Coase II- there is no perfect market; must include transactional costs (cost of reaching an accord btw parties), which can cause the outcome to flip- less valuable activity can continue b/c of the high transaction cost of stopping the activity; fewer people affected = higher transactional costs (Turleyworks ex.)
- Intentional Harm
- Background
- Intent
- Rest. § 1: Conduct is intentional if the actor:
- desires the result/consequence (“purpose” intent); OR
- knows or believes the result is substantially certain to occur (“knowledge” intent)
- little boy knew old lady would be hurt when he pulled chair out in Garret v. Daly
- Children may be held liable of intent
- intent inferred from conduct, not motive
- Transferred intent- A hits C when intending to hit B; C claims transferred intent; 1st you must establish original intent
- Traditional defense- consent
- Basic Types
- Physical Harm: Trespass to person, land, and chattels
- Tresspass to person
- Vosburg v. Putney
- Rule Violation- Putney kicks Π in shin, lost use of leg
- held responsible, even for unforeseen damages
- Rule- For intent, it is sufficient to show rule violation, the natural cause of which is injury
- Trespass to Land- intent to enter someone else’s land, even if by reasonably mistake (i.e. because unaware it’s someone else’s property)
- Trespass to Chattels- intentional dispossession of a thing; loss in valuable int’st
- trespass to chattel (stolen but returnable) vs. conversion (destroyed, unreturnable)
- Rst. § 218, 19: Liable for direct/ indirect phys. contact causing impairment: of condition, quality, value.
- Intangible property: Intel v. Hamidi- trespass to chattels claim fails- emails did not damage the computer system
- Physical Harm: Conversion
- Rst. § 222- intentional exercise of control over chattel, which seriously interferes w/Π’s right to control
- Moore v. Regents of Univ. Cal.- organ removed from body, used for science ($). Usually put in trash so NO conversion.
- RULE: custom of chattel disposal effects determination of conversion
- Possible Defenses:
- slippery slope
- slippery slope- if you say removal of tissue is conversion, huge # of issues
- bright light argument- say this is not priv. property or slippery slope
- floodgates- if tissue is priv. property, thousands of patients whose tissue was used in research
- Physical Harm: DEFENSES to Intentional Torts
- Consensual Defenses- consent vitiates intent
- Rst. § 892: consent when one is willing for conduct to occur
- Need- Π’s subjective state of mind consent
- Don’t Need- communication to Δ
- Apparent consent- Π’s words or conduct is enough (i.e. implied consent in the O’Brien case- stick out arm, stand in line, receive unwanted vaccination)
- Mohr v. Williams- Dr. diagnoses left ear, while Π sedated, operates on other ear civil assault and battery
- Rule: Need consent
- Issue: Patient’s awareness of consent, and to what
- Emergency Rule- Dr.s are not required to get consent if a person is seriously injured (i.e. unconscious or severe pain) and time is of the essence
- Proper, informed consent is required
- Canterbury v. Spence- Π has back surgery, left unattended, not instruct to stay still, falls off bed
- Issue: Duty to disclose risks in acquisition of consent?
- Rule: “Informed consent” is required
- Rule: You can’t consent to something illegal
- Hudson v. Craft- Π, minor, goes to carnival, injured in boxing match
- Issue: Did consent to illegal activity negate Δ’s responsibility?
- Rule: If you are part of a protected class (i.e. minor), court may ignore consent.
- Rule: Public policy can require consent- duty to disclose.
- I.e. If you have an STD, you have a duty to disclose (or be held liable). If you do disclose, even if transmission occurs, no liability.
- Insanity: Insane/estate usually held liable
- McGuire v. Almy- Π, nurse caretaker, insane Δ hit nurse on head w/table leg
- Rule: Insane held liable for their intentional torts.
- Court uses cheapest cost avoider to determine family is CCA. Turley- nurse/hospital CCA b/c they can get insurance, and nurse knows the danger.
- Self-Defense
- RST § 63:Rule: May only use reasonable force against imminent harm.
- Rule: May only use commensurate force.
- May not escalate the encounter by increasing the violence.
- Rule: You do not have to retreat.
- But may not retaliate once danger is passed. Battered women syndrome not accepted- viewed as retaliation.
- Rule: Mistaken self-defense must be reasonable.
- Courvoisier v. Raymond- Δ fending off intruders, confuses cop w/intruder and shoots
- Rule: Reasonable, mistaken belief of self defense is reasonable.
- 3rd party privilege to defend others under same conditions and by same means as one may defend self.
- Defense of Property
- RST § 77: Rule: May use reasonable force; MAY NOT use force calculated to cause serious bodily injury or death in defense of property. Human life more sacred than property. May use molitormanus- laying gentle hands.
- Curtilage- the area around a home that is protected
- Rule: May NOT have lethal devices that cannot distinguish btw friend/ foe.
- Bird v. Holbrook- walled garden w/spring gun kills kid
- Rule: Human life worth more than property; lethal traps illegal.
- Rule: Notice is necessary to prevent liability for use of non-lethal devices that can cause injury that are not patent (i.e. electric fence, hidden barbed wire). Patent (visible) barbed-wire is a warning itself.
- Controversial: Castle Doctrine/ Make My Day- whenever someone intrudes your domicile, you may use the full range of self-protection (i.e. lethal force ok)
- Recapture of Chattels
- RST § 100: Limited self-help privilege- reasonable force requirement, recapture must begin promptly
- Kirby v. Foster- Π has gained rightful possession of $, Δ fights for it back
- Rule: Reasonable force may be used ONLY when dispossession was unlawful
- Necessity
- An otherwise trespass/conversion on Π allowed in preservation of life or property.
- Ploof v. Putnam- Π, family sailing in storm, moor to Δ’s dock, dock’s owner unmoors boat
- Rule: There is a duty to allow acts of necessity in order to preserve human life.
- Vincent v. Lake Erie Transportation Co.- Δ re-ties failed ropes of boat to dock during storm, dock damaged by boat
- Rule: Privilege of private necessity does not negate duty to pay for damages.
- Turley: Reverse arg.- dock owner may be CCA (insurance, internalize costs). Ability to sue for lost opportunity costs unclear.
- Public necessity- “champion of the common good”; if acting for public good, may destroy public property and not be held liable
- Gvmt may always use this argument, but gvmt has waived much of its immunity
- i.e. U.S. gvmt compensates war-time victims
- Most states have restricted it to keep ppl from claiming it
- Emotional/Dignitary Harm: Assault
- RST § 21: Assault- intent to cause reasonable apprehension of imminent battery
- Need: Intention + Act
- Δ must have intent to cause offensive contact or imminent apprehension (Π’s awareness of threat)
- Rule: Mere words are not enough to constitute assault
- Emotional/Dignitary Harm: OFFENSIVE BATTERY
- RST § 18: Battery: Intent to cause offensive contact + offensive contact
- If no intention, then only negligent, reckless act, NOT offensive battery.
- Emotional/Dignitary Harm: False Imprisonment
- False Imprisonment- Δ intends to confine Π w/in boundaries fixed by Δ, and Π is conscious of the confinement or harmed by it
- Intent is all that’s necessary; mistake is not a defense.
- False arrest = false imprisonment
- Future threats do not equal false imprisonment
- Bird v. Jones- Π disallowed to continue down blocked highway
- Rule: Effective confinement required for false imprisonment.
- Possible Scenarios:
- Acts of negligence (i.e. stuck on elevator/plane) do not equal false imprisonment.
- Confined in a room, but no restraint? Not false imprisonment
- Confined in a room, but a high window gives escape? False imprisonment
- Coblyn v. Kennedy’s- old man trapped in store after suspected shoplifting
- Rule: Short-term ‘imprisonment’ against shoplifters ok if reasonable (equivalent to citizen’s arrest). Time/place/manner is critical to reasonableness.
- Emotional/Dignitary Harm: Intentional Infliction of Emotional Distress
- Usually parasitic- attached to another claim; courts disfavor IIED w/o parasitic attachment
- Emotional Distress- when Δ intentionally inflicts through extreme/outrageous conduct w/a causal connection severe emotional distress
- 3rd parties difficulty
- RST- majority rule- Family members, if present, may recover; 3rd parties can recover, but (slight) bodily injury/ physical contact is required.
- Mishandling a corpse- subject to liability for IIED; only family members can recover; punitive damages sometimes allowed; shared crim/civil liability; aggravating element- culture
- Beckstrom’s Socio-Biological Theory- “last of the line” arguments should be allowed; judges leery b/c suggests some children worth more than others (i.e. adopted ones); courts should respect impulse of importance of replicating DNA
- Strict Liability and Negligence
- Brown v. Kendall- man tries to separate fighting dogs, accidently hits Π w/stick
- Rule: Negligence is deciding standard: If Δ was using “ordinary care”- no liability.
- Fletcher v. Rylands 1- Δ’s reservoir leaked, damaging Π’s coal mine
- Rule: Δ is strictly liable regardless of intent/negligence.
- Rylands 2: Rule: Strict liability applies to damage caused by activities/items originating from Δ’s property (i.e. cattle, privy, alkaline works, water reservoirs at the time)
- Posner: Negligence is the most effective system; strict liability forces cost-internalization, leaving it to the market to dispose of inefficient activities
- DuncanKennedy- here, class issue, courts are protecting the nobility
- Rylands 3: Rule: Rylands is strictly liable b/c non-natural use (creation of reservoir). If natural use (mine coal, water percolates through to mine below)- not liable.
- Defense only if act of god causes the damage
- U.S. quickly rejected having a dominant system of strict liability
- Brown v. Collins- horse startles, breaks lamp post
- Rule- SL not applicable b/c horses common and Δ used reasonable care
- If U.S. had applied Rylands test during Indust. Rev. would have cut growth dramatically
- Powell v. Fall- sparks from steam engine cause fire on Π’s property
- Rule: When statute clearly states liability, common-law supplanted- NEGLIGENCE PER SE.
- Most statutes set a minimum standard of care; compliance w/doesn’t mean you’re reasonable/ not liable. May be found negligent per se, but this doesn’t ensure liability. Must still find unreasonableness was legal cause of injury. However, reasonableness never plays a role in strict liability.
- Holmes- p. 146, 77- importance of an objective standard
- Strict Liability and Negligence: Modern Times
- Negligence (question of degree) vs. Strict Liability (Check social attitude toward conduct; then liable or not).
- Stone v. Bolton 1- Π Stone hit by cricket ball from cricket ground close to public road. Δ found negligent.
- Rule: One is negligent if there was a reasonably foreseeable risk of severe injury w/no effort to mitigate.
- Bolton 2: Δ prevails; Rule: In negligence, consider “question of degree”- 1. remoteness of risk of injury and 2. seriousness of consequences. Liability based on negligence- reasonable standard of care.
- D. Kennedy would say law is favoring upper class.
- Proper rule for sports teams (negligence v. SL)? Turley- SL, stadiums are CCA (most information, insurance, internalization of cost, gives business incentive to be safer, forces businesses to bear the cost of their activities or be forced out)
- Hammontree v. Jenner- epileptic driver crashes into store, injuring Π
- Rule: No negligence if taking due care and suddenly overcome by medical condition.
- Rule: SL should apply to unforeseeable instances.
- Negligence
- Introduction
- Turley: Determination of the ‘reasonable person’ standard is relative to the situation, culture, society, etc. NOT just duty.
- Elements (§ 281):
- duty by Δ to act/refrain from acting
- breach of that duty by Δ’s failure to conform to required standard
- sufficient causal connection btw the negligent conduct and Π’s injury
- Actual harm that is measureable/compensable
- and… w/in scope of liability
- i.e. proximate cause- not necessary though
- RST § 282: Negligence- “conduct falling below the standard established by law for the protection of others against unreasonable risk of harm”
- The test is objective
- Care must be reasonable, not perfect
- The Reasonable Person
- Knowledge, Experience, and Perception
- Reasonable person consists of: Δ’s knowledge and observations, what average society would do (calculation of the risks), Δ’s possible superior intelligence in an extreme case
- Knowledge Common to Community
- The conduct of a ‘prudent man’ is applied to negligence, which is an objective standard.
- Vaughan v. Menlove- ‘dumb’ farmer, dangerous hay rick, burns neighbor’s property
- Rule: Sub-standard intelligence (subjective arg.) no excuse; must still meet objective standard (or everyone would claim to be dumb).
- Holmes- the law uses an objective standard. The law sees you not as God sees you.
- Activities Requiring Skill
- Performing a licensed/ special skill activity mitigates consideration of personal attributes (age, impairments, etc.), holding the person to the standard of that class.
- Daniels v. Evans- 19 yr. Π old killed when driving a motorcycle
- Rule: If participating in an adult activity, held to an adult standard of care.
- Age
- Children
- If adult activity, held to reasonable, adult standard (Daniels).
- Otherwise, children who commit negligent acts are held to a subjective standard, considering the age, maturity, and intelligence of the child. < 4 (no capacity for reasonability); 4 – 7/11 (presumption of no capacity); By 11, presumption of capacity; After 14, considered to have capacity.
- Rule: Licensed Activity- MUST meet reasonable person standard.
- Roberts v. Ring- 77 yr. old man w/sight/hearing issues hits 7 yr. old
- Physicians
- Majority- Reasonable person = customary practice of reasonably well-qualified practitioner, licensed or not.
- Minority- reasonable person = “- - -” + local conditions
- Physical Characteristics/ Disabilities
- Rule: Public areas must be made safe for all; foreseeability requires anticipation of blindness, height differences, and even intoxication (public policy incentive).
- Fletcher v. City of Aberdeen- City leaves unfenced ditch by sidewalk, blind Π falls, injured
- Mental Capacity
- Rule: Insanity is a defense to negligence ONLY when sudden.
- Breunig v. American Family Ins.- Δ has history of mental illness, thinks God is directing her car, crashes into Π
- Question to ask: should Δ have known or taken preventative steps?
- Calculus of Risk
- General:
- Two levels:
- Commonsense version of negligence
- Economic version based on costs and benefits- ‘calculus’ of risk
- A reasonable person is not required to avoid all accidents or always pay liability
- In negligence, you may kill/hurt a person and not be liable; assumption that some acts are reasonable
- Risk-Utility Test: Hand Formula:
If B < P x L liability for negligence