Economics focus
The reserve army

Feb 12th 2004
From The Economist print edition


The unemployment rate is only the beginning of the problem

RARELY does an economic indicator provide as much fodder for politicians and pundits as the unemployment rate. Far more than, say, current accounts or capacity utilisation, unemployment is something everyone can understand: you are either in work, not in work, or looking for work. As such, it is easily seized upon as an indicator of the broader health of an economy, or even of workers' eagerness to revolt.

The issue of unemployment has loomed especially large in America in recent months. That is partly because there are presidential elections in November, and much will hinge on whether George Bush can convince voters that an apparently booming economy is producing jobs. A glance at the unemployment rate would seem to give him the answer he wants. The unemployment rate has fallen from a post-recession peak of 6.3% in June to 5.6% last month, though that is still higher than the 5.0% that many economists consider to be the “natural rate” of unemployment—one that results merely from the normal or “frictional” patterns of job gains and losses at any one time.

But the unemployment rate is, in fact, a poor measure of economic health. It is defined as the fraction of the people in the labour force—those who are actively seeking work and available for it—who cannot find a job. And it relies on surveys to determine who is, in fact, actively seeking work rather than enjoying a spot of leisure. It is that subjectivity that makes the unemployment rate such a flawed statistic. A better question by far is how many people are employed—ie, are being paid by someone for doing something, since this should be less subject to doubt.

Or so you might have thought. Yet there has been a fierce debate in America recently over even this humble statistic. That is because the number employed in America is also still measured using surveys, and the two that are widely used tell different stories. One is taken of over 400,000 firms with formal payrolls. Another asks 60,000 households whether people in them are working. But both are hostage to the usual limitations of using small samples to estimate employment for the whole economy, though obviously to different degrees. They are, moreover, subject to big revisions. And both have their advantages.

The payroll survey uses a bigger, more easily verifiable sample. On the other hand, the household survey may better capture a rise in jobs among new small businesses and the self-employed, both of which seem to have accounted for a lot of new employment in the recent recovery. According to the household measure, nearly 139m Americans were in work in January, even more than had jobs at the height of the boom in March 2000. By the payroll measure, some 130m were in work—a fall of nearly 2% since employment peaked.

Left-leaning pundits naturally prefer the payroll survey. The Bush administration and its friends prefer the household version. Still, even the latter's figures would make job growth in the current economic recovery anaemic by historical standards.

Concerns over employment data are not just an American problem. According to a recent report from Barclays Capital, Germany's employment statistics may be overstating the numbers of self-employed because of a government initiative to subsidise previously unemployed workers in starting their own business. Combined with other shenanigans, this may produce an army of “hidden unemployed” of 1.4m, estimates the report, some 30% more than the number of officially unemployed. In Japan, the unemployment rate has never risen above 5.5% in recent years, despite a decade-long economic funk. That is in part because firms are reluctant to sack workers for social reasons.

Flawed though they may be, the employment numbers are of fundamental importance. Two crucial questions for economic output and for the suffering caused by unemployment are: what portion of the working-age population does not work and how many of those that do not work want to do so?

The international brigade

Regardless of which survey you believe, more people of working age are at work in America than in Europe. America's employment rate is just over 70%—almost ten percentage points higher than Europe's. In other words, less than a third of working-age Americans are not in work, whereas in Europe the figure is closer to 40%, though the gap between the two economies has been closing in recent years, as America's employment rate has fallen and Europe's has risen.

Many of those that do not work would almost certainly like to. By the OECD's reckoning, the ranks of those who could be mobilised are thus far bigger than those that are formally classed as unemployed. Indeed, in most countries, according to the OECD, there are far more gains to be had in bringing inactive workers into work than in reducing unemployment to its “natural” rate. In Italy, for example, the OECD reckons that more than a fifth of the working-age population could be brought into work, and some 17% in Spain and Greece.

In the euro area, the relatively lower employment rate explains much of the region's lower GDP per person. And low employment is often the fault of misguided policies that discourage people from working, such as high payroll taxes; marginal income taxes that penalise the work of a lower-paid spouse; rules that make sacking workers expensive; and generous benefits that encourage the work-shy to be classed as disabled, to name but a few.

Such structural problems play a huge role in the differences in the wealth of nations. The trouble is that fixing them can be politically fraught. Just ask Gerhard Schröder, Germany's chancellor, who resigned this month as head of his party, because of resistance to a package of modest reforms. Having jobs is one thing; working quite another.

The Truth About the Job Numbers
The “self-employed” are not this bad economy’s saviors.

By Robert B. Reich Web Exclusive: 09.09.04 Print Friendly | Email Article
Last Friday's household survey showed the unemployment rate dipping to 5.4 percent in August, which isn't bad by historic standards. But last Friday's payroll survey showed that employers created only 144,000 payroll jobs in August, which is pretty awful given that the economy needs at least 150,000 just to keep up with new workers coming into the labor market. So the obvious question: Do we have anything to celebrate this post Labor-Day week?

Well, let's take a closer look. The more upbeat household survey is compiled every month by a team of surveyors from the Bureau of Labor Statistics who visit a random sample of 60,000 homes around country, and ask: "are you working?" If the answer they get is "no," the next question is "are you looking for work?" Only if the answer to that second question is "yes" -- I'm looking for work -- is the person counted as "unemployed." This means that everyone who'd like to work but has given up looking because they've tried and can't find any work, is not included as being among the unemployed. There's the additional problem that some people who aren't working but are embarrassed to admit it will say they are.

The payroll survey, by contrast, asks a much larger and different sample -- 400,000 employers, who employ about a third of the entire workforce -- how many employees they've added over past month. No guesswork there. Just look at the payrolls. There's only one rub: The payroll survey doesn't include everyone who's become self-employed.

Now, this would be a problem if self-employment were a real alternative. But that's not what the evidence shows. A new research paper from the San Francisco Federal Reserve finds that the number of "self-employed" rises during weak economies and falls when people can find payroll jobs. In other words, being "self-employed" doesn't necessarily mean you're making enough money to live on. All it might mean is you can't find a payroll job and you're calling yourself "self-employed." No big surprise there.

Bottom line: Employers are still reluctant to hire. And it's not hard to figure out why. Demand for their goods and services remains soft -- because consumers, who are also workers, don't have enough money in their pockets or confidence in their jobs and paychecks to flood back into the malls.

The following Questions all make reference to the first article:

The reserve army

Feb 12th 2004
From The Economist print edition

1. What is the importance of an unemployment rate that does or does not determine who is “enjoying a spot of leisure” in paragraph three? Are there any other reasons the unemployment rate tends to over- or under-state actual unemployment? Consider: discouraged workers, the role of underemployed workers, and other skew factors in the rate.

Note - Your answer should separately analyze how the inclusion or exclusion of at least three groups in the official unemployment rate results in an official rate that over- or under-states actual unemployment. State clearly for each of the three groups you choose to analyze whether the fact our official rate includes or excludes them results in EITHER an overstated or understated rate. For some groups you will explain why the fact our official rate excludes (or includes) them results in understatement. For others you will explain why their inclusion or exclusion in the official data results in overstatement. However, for any one skew factor, you will not say it results in understatement and/or overstatement (specify one or the other for each skew factor).

Skew factor you must analyze: Those “enjoying a spot of leisure” (included)

Skew factors you could analyze (any two):

Students (excluded)

Military (excluded)

Those in the informal economy (excluded)

Underemployed e.g. part-time workers (included)

Those who have given up looking for a job (excluded)

Use example #’s e.g. your starting point is that the rate as currently reported is

# looking *100= Unemp Rate ------à 7million *100= 5%

Labor Force (LF) 150 million

2. What is meant by “The Reserve Army” (the article’s title)? Explain the argument in paragraph ten that more gains for many economies could come from (Policy 1) bringing working-age people who are not looking for a job back into the workforce than (Policy 2) lowering unemployment to the natural rate of unemployment. Gains should be explained in terms of number of new workers or dollar value of additional output (use example #’s).

3. How could the natural rate of unemployment itself be reduced? Specifically how could (a) structural unemployment and (b) frictional unemployment be reduced? You may want to review: “Chapter 6 Focus - Defining the Natural Rate of Unemployment and Analyzing its Determinants” to answer this question.

Note: the answer is not to simply declare a new estimate of the natural rate; suggest policies for (a) and (b) that would alter the real economic situation in a way that would compel economists to change their estimate of the natural rate to reflect the new reality.

4.  Paragraph five states: “According to the household measure, nearly 139m Americans were in work in January, even more than had jobs at the height of the boom in March 2000. By the payroll measure, some 130m were in work—a fall of nearly 2% since employment peaked.” In what ways does the fact that the difference between the two numbers (9m) is due to people reporting self-employment in the household survey improve that survey’s accuracy in measuring jobs and output, and in what ways does the inclusion of such workers worsen its accuracy?

Additional Sources

Info on Students (re: Question 1):

http://www.bls.gov/news.release/pdf/hsgec.pdf

It deals with the whole population age 16-24, including students

Interestingly, in this age group, 16.4 million do not attend school.

21 million do, with roughly half in high school and half in college.

9.7 million are in high school and 11.3 million are in college, who have labor force participation rates of 29.4% and 54% respectively.

Overview of Employment Data:

http://www.bls.gov/news.release/empsit.t02.htm

Partially illustrative of students, ages 16-19

Contains:

Both sexes, 16 to 19 years

Civilian labor force...... 771

Participation rate...... 28.9

Employed 582

Employment-population ratio...... 21.8

Unemployed...... 189

Unemployment rate...... 24.5

http://www.bls.gov/cps/

http://www.bls.gov/news.release/empsit.toc.htm

mainly to click the first link on this page:

http://www.bls.gov/news.release/empsit.nr0.htm

http://www.shadowstats.com/article/54

5