The Third Term

Stefano Harney

The Third Term

1.Governance is a third term, beyond sovereignty or

governmentality. Although the term governance may still mark a form

of government. It is longer only a political term. Nor is governance a term of economy, as in corporate governance, or least not completely. Governance is

now also a term of political economy, or more exactly, because the older connotations of that phrase may deceive us, we might say governance is a political form of economic production.

2.Sovereignty establishes the public and private. Governmentality

makes this establishment of the private productive, through the

production of the public. Governance today marks the emergence of

the public as directly productive. No longer is the public, in all

its micropolitics of subjectivity and macropolitics of population, an

instrument for creating a private that can then be exploited. Today

the public itself in all its anti-social glory, because the public is

the most anti-social moment of capitalist society, is also a direct

and dominant source of capitalist wealth, dominant in tendency. This is because the public holds all of the social qualities of the general intellect up to the

light, making the general intellect obvious even in its disfiguration

in the figure of the public, and offering up this captured aspect of

the general intellect for exploitation.

3.Governance puts the public to work, or, perhaps we could say,

after Mario Tronti, governance is the new labour process. Mario

Tronti said the capitalist brings only this labour process, brings

only work, while the worker brings her class relation, her

socialisation, and her living labour, in short she brings the

capital. Today we could say the capitalist brings only governance,

as for instance one might understand the Davos meetings, or the rise

of the business schools, or the international efforts of

African debt relief, all experiments in governance as labour process,

in governance as the effort to locate the general intellect and, as

Tiziana Terranova says, to harness it, to ride it. The capitalist brings

governance as a desperate attempt to arrange a labour process beyond

his control. And how does he do this? How does governance work as a

labour process?

The Mosquito

4.Being in public is different from being public, and being in

public has always been criminal. Once that criminality was connected

to sovereignty, as in reckless eyeballing and the African slave. The

male African slave needed to be in public to work, but if his being

in public threatened the idea of being public, he could be accused of

looking at a white woman, being in public, ‘reckless eyeballing,’ and

punished or killed. The public was dominated by a sovereign

definition here. Later this is not enough, and perhaps was never

enough, for labour discipline. Malcolm X tells the story of a

hanging in London of a pickpocket, and even while the pickpocket was

being hanged, other pickpockets worked the crowd watching the

hanging. Clearly sovereign power was not enough for the kind of

labour discipline emerging in London at that time. Governmentality

names the experiments that come to supplement this power, governmentality if the resistance to the self-organisation of the pickpockets.

5.But now to be in public, but not public, is a form of direct

sabotage of the labour process. This is why we see the disconnection

between the ever smoother operations of governmentality at new ever

greater levels of differential inclusion, and at the same time the

more regressive uses of prisons, police violence, rendition, and

social censure, co-existing in one space, and one might add kettling. Today being in public threatens not only the operation of the public as the process of securing private

exploitation, it also threatens expropriation itself. And today expropriation, contemporary primitive accumulation, disaster capitalism, immaterial labour, there are many names, is central to capitalist accumulation.

6.Social time, as Toni Negri says, cannot be recognized as such by

capital, as pure social potentiality. But it can be recognized as

waiting time, if the wait is for work, as Paolo Virno says. We can

call this exhibition time, after Virno, the time during which we

exhibit to all who pass our potential to labour. And this is the key

to establishing the difference between being in public and being

public. Because how do we exhibit this willingness to stand beside

production and yet to attend to it (rather than having it attend to

us)? In other words, what does ‘sabotage of the capitalist capture

of the general intellect’ look like? I would say, it looks like a

lack of governance.

7.And what does governance look like? I would say in large part it

looks like the continuous production and exhibition of self-

generated, intelligible public interests. This is not just our

interest in the public, but our interest in generating the public

through the production of more interests, more politics if you like,

even more politics of difference, as long as this difference is

public, and therefore not different. The exhibition of willing

labour-power in the form of public interests is increasingly what

composes the public. And it is the exhibition that governance seeks

to organize. And why public interests? Because public interests are

a way to capture all the social cooperation, all the social

interests, that reside in the general intellect, and that are, as

Michael Hardt and Toni Negri have taught us, the chief source of

capitalist wealth today. Governance that provokes the production and

exhibition of public interests therefore mines the wealth of the

general intellect for what it cannot reach without the aid of all

those who identify, volunteer, and offer up their public interests.

8.This is the way, I suggest, to understand the Eighteenth Brumaire

of Barack Obama. American interest in politics under this ‘fetish of

the public interest’ is a manifestation of the overwhelming labour

discipline of that society, the overwhelming willingness to identify,

volunteer and offer up public interests, or in other words the

overwhelmingly willingness to exhibit the capacity for capitalist

work. On the other hand, it is also the way to understand ‘the

mosquito’ – a device used by the English police to disperse young

people in public squares and malls by using a high-pitched noise only

people under 20 years of age can hear. Those who do not exhibit this

capacity for capitalist work must be cleared from the public space

because it is the site of capitalist exploitation today. Rather than

close the public space, as in earlier phases of neo-liberalism still

trying to invent governance, it must be open for production and

appropriation, but only for this. It is also a way to understand the movement from the statement ‘there is no such thing as society’ to ‘Cool Britannia’ to the ‘Big Society.’

NGOs, Art Museums, and the Metroversity

9.As I have said elsewhere, the laboratory of the production of

public interests is the NGO. The ethos of the NGO is that

populations must be provoked into identifying and volunteering their

own public interests. The NGO regards it as counter-productive to

speak for the illegal migrant. Only the illegal migrant knows the

contours of her own public interests. An illegal migrant ought to

know her rights, says the NGO. In this boiling cauldron of neo-

liberalism and civil society was this new meaning of governance born,

and from there has it spread.

10.This is also the key in my view to the creative industries. It

is not a question of business invading culture or even of culture

invading business. On the one hand, the creative industries do offer

new private sources of exploitation as scholars like Andrew Ross have

shown us. On the other hand as I have tried to show, the business

school has no subject except itself, and is therefore filled with

creativity, politics, and cultural forms. But these two sides alone

of the creative industries leave out its real attraction to capital

as a vehicle of governance, as a new labour process carved through

the general intellect, strip-mining social attention and opinion.

The creative industries are harnessed as the way art makes audiences,

and audiences make public interests, in the form of taste, attention,

prohibition, pleasure, and from all of this, new source of value. This is art

as governance, as labour process. The market is a market in what can

be revealed about audiences through new art. This is what is worth

millions.

11.And finally the metroversity, which thanks to the Edu-factory

collective has come so much into view for me. What seems important

here is the reversal of the visibility of the general equivalent.

Broadly one could say the university was a place where one acted on

the possibility of an original use-value while suspecting (correctly

as we see in Christopher Newfield’s work) the world of exchange

outside was also inside. Now, in the university this suspicion has

become common sense. The university is overtly the place of the

production of knowledge as exchange-value, and no one has any

illusions about it. Curiously outside the university, however, one

is now supposed to act like original use-value is possible. Out in

the city one acts as one used to act in the university, like original

use-value is possible while suspecting (again correctly) that

exchange-value reigns. Thus we fetishize public difference and

accept pure command over our time as once was the case in the

nostalgic university. Taken together these two conditions and their

reversal and blending are for me the definition of the metroversity, a version, I will suggest below, of a larger public-private partnership against the common.

Dumb Insolence of the Undercommons

12.Fred Moten and I tried to think about the metroversity through

its workers, through the undercommons produced by the self-

organisation of these workers. (In the US the metroversity also

remains a form of rural patronage as well as tending toward an urban

social factory of a new kind.) For us, the undercommons is, from the

revolutionary point of view, the self-organisation of the

incommensurate. From the point of view of capital, the undercommons

is the unacknowledged self-organisation of the despised, discounted,

and anti-social. The first act of self-organisation in the

undercommons is a refusal of subjectivation through, and only

through, self-organisation. This disidentification through self-

organisation is also, for us, not a prerequisite to what Toni Negri

calls the common management (gestione) of the commons, but the

potential of that organisation. By the way this gestione is the missing piece in any stupidity about the tragedy of the commons.

13.Those who work in the undercommons of the metroversity are often

said to be dumb, and often said to be insolent. They must not go out

in public. They do not exhibit the right attitude. They are workers

from the darkness of the private. They might bring the university into disrepute as they say here in Britain. To governance they offer only dumb

insolence. But they seek a way to be together that does not require

explanation or interests first, and is only of use to others who seek

a similar ensemble. This is why for us translation is crucial and

the work of Sandro Mezzadra and his colleagues so important. But

dumb insolence is also about bodies and senses and social affect, not

just cognition and language. It is also about, paradoxically,

laughter, music, touch, and the invitation to an ensemble of these

affects and comprehensions that is not issued but remains possible,

even necessary, nonetheless. We might say that the undercommons is what remains of the common under governance. It is its remaining form which to governance looks too informal, without form, free of form we might also want to say. It looks like wasted time, free time. But the undercommons is the regenerative form of the common, where not just form, but form-giving resides, where the capacity to self-organisation regenerates.

14.Free Time

We might also say then that governance is the resistance to the common, a resistance that never fully succeeds. This would mean that the idea of governance as an initiative, for instance to create expanded comparison and management, or to create markets, needs to be rethought.

Governance has neither the ability to make forms, to organise, nor to know itself ahead of time, to see, as it were, the form in the head or feel it in the body. The common is prior to governance, but so too, is something else. This is accumulation. Accumulation in the common, and capitalist accumulation. Now we know today that capitalist accumulation leads with finance. And finance itself it increasingly driven by a kind of ethics of productivity whose vigilance finds all about it unsatisfactory. It is this vigilance that calls for governance.

Governance sees a kind of formlessness and calls for form, but of course governance, being about nothing, contra Rose and company, is only made into form by the very commons who are said not to have it. It is not a matter of giving form to the commons however, a Leninist formulation, but of the commons giving form to matter.

  1. The Real Public-Private Partnership

This is the real public-private partnership. Finance operates today with an ethics of the other based on a judgement about productivity. Compared to the screens of the broker where measurement is apparently still possible, most other wealth-making operation look sub-optimal, and no amount of performativity in hospitals or universities can overcome the basic opacity of immaterial labour today. Only finance is clear. As a result finance finds its material links to other workplaces always insufficient, and its desire to accumulate new links always frustrated. Instead of productivity it finds something like free time. Indeed with the rise of finance free time finally comes into relief as precisely the opposite, the opposition which is really the provocation, the organisation that must be expropriated or destroyed. To accomplish the logistics of these links, it calls forth governance in a public-private partnership, demanding through the political what it cannot find through the directly economic. Interests are identified and the ends of these interests are fastened like a universal plug to new sources of wealth, newly configured labour, to what was common, to seemed formless, to what did not give itself to finance but was given to governance.

Extracted from the common we have what must be called today not strategized populations, but logistical populations. Logistics is the art and science of fastening the tentacles of capitalist accumulation to the common. Logistics is the contemporary form of capitalist expropriation, and governance is its key operation, the moment when it produces the public, and the private, against the common. And the undercommons is the condition of logistical failure.

END

1