In association with
Environmental Futures Limited
Valuing Our Natural Environment
Final Report - Annexes
NR0103
For Department for Environment, Food and Rural Affairs
20th March 2006
eftec, 16 Percy Street, London W1T 1DT; tel: 0207 580 5383; fax: 0207 580 5385; ; www.eftec.co.uk
Valuing Our Natural Environment – Final Report - Annexes
Table of Contents
ANNEX 1: Fiches for Valuation Methods 1
A1.1 Economic Valuation Methods 2
A1.1.1 Market Price Approaches 2
A1.1.2 Production Function Approach 5
A1.1.3 Hedonic Property Pricing 7
A1.1.4 Travel Cost Method 11
A1.1.5 Random Utility Models 15
A1.1.6 Contingent Valuation Method 17
A1.1.7 Choice Modelling 22
A1.1.8 Benefits Transfer 26
A1.2 Deliberative and Participatory Valuation Methods 30
A1.2.1 Questionnaires and Interviews 30
A1.2.2 Focus groups, In-depth groups 34
A1.2.3 Citizens' Juries and Consensus Conferences 38
A1.2.4 Health-Based Valuation Approaches 41
A1.2.5 Q-methodology 46
A1.2.6 Delphi Surveys, Systematic Reviews 49
A1.3 Decision Support Methods 53
A1.3.1 Cost-Benefit Analysis 53
A1.3.2 Cost-Effectiveness Analysis 57
A1.3.3 Multi-Criteria Analysis 60
A1.3.4 Life Cycle Analysis 66
A1.4 Alternative Measures of Prosperity 69
A1.4.1 Human Development Index 69
A1.4.2 Index of Sustainable Economic Welfare 70
A1.4.3 Green National Product and Genuine Savings 76
A1.4.4 UK Sustainable Development Indicators 78
Annex 1 References 81
ANNEX 2: Literature Overview and References 88
A2.1 Overview of Literature 88
A2.1.1 Economic Valuation Methods 88
A2.1.2 Deliberative and Participatory Valuation Methods 92
A2.1.3 Decision Support Methods 95
A2.2 References 98
A2.2.1 Economic Valuation Methods 98
A2.2.2 Deliberative and Participatory Valuation Methods 110
A2.2.3 Decision Support Methods 121
ANNEX 3: Summaries of Policy Consultation and Workshops 128
A3.1 Expert Consultation – Summary of Responses 128
A3.1.1 Method 128
A3.1.2 Overall Assessment 128
A3.2 Policy Maker Consultation - Summary of Responses 132
A3.2.1 The Consultees 132
A3.2.2 Introductory Questions 132
A3.2.3 General Information for Decision-Making 133
A3.2.4 Information Gaps 134
A3.2.5 Value of the Natural Environment 137
A3.2.6 Value Information 138
A3.2.7 Using Different Kinds/Sources of Information 140
A3.2.8 Environmental Valuation Techniques 141
A3.2.9 Future Needs 143
A3.3 Policy Workshop Summaries 144
A3.3.1 First Workshop - February 1, 2006, London 144
A3.3.2 Second Policy Workshop - February 2, 2006, London 151
eftec March 2006
Valuing Our Natural Environment – Final Report - Annex1
ANNEX 1: Fiches for Valuation Methods
Each fiche presented in this Annex covers all or some of the following headings for each method:
· Objectives of the method;
· Value concept encapsulated;
· Theoretical basis;
· Process of implementation;
· Data needs;
· Other practical issues for implementation (time frame, expertise requirements);
· Principal outputs;
· Transferability of outputs;
· Key uses – decision making context(s);
· Key uses – coverage of the natural environment;
· Discussion (limits, criticisms etc. as relevant to each method);
· Consideration of distributional impacts;
· Advantages and disadvantages; and
· Conflicts and synergies with other methods.
The following methods are reported here:
Economic Valuation Methods
Market Price Approaches
Production Function Approach
Hedonic Property Pricing
Travel Cost Method
Random Utility Models
Contingent Valuation Method
Choice Modelling
Benefits Transfer
Deliberative and Participatory Valuation Methods
Questionnaires and interviews
Focus groups, In-depth groups
Citizens' Jury and Consensus Conferences
Health-based valuation approaches (QALYs, DALYs, HYEs etc)
Q-methodology
Delphi surveys, systematic reviews
Decision Support Methods
Cost-benefit analysis
Cost-effectiveness analysis
Multi-Criteria Analysis
Life Cycle Analysis
Alternative Measures of Prosperity
Human Development Index (HDI)
Index of Sustainable Economic Welfare
Green National Product and Genuine Savings
UK Sustainable Development Indicators
A1.1 Economic Valuation Methods
A1.1.1 Market Price Approaches
A1.1.1.1 Objectives
Pricing approaches to valuing environmental goods and services consider the costs that arise in relation to the provision of environmental goods and services, which may be directly observed from markets. Summarised here under this heading are a number of different approaches: opportunity cost; cost of alternatives; mitigation costs; shadow project costs; cost of illness and subsidy cost.
A1.1.1.2 Value concept encapsulated
Application of pricing approaches typically informs on either direct or indirect use values associated with environmental goods and services (but see discussion below). Pricing approaches are best thought of as providing a ‘proxy value’ for environmental goods and services.
A1.1.1.3 Theoretical basis
Pricing approaches are ‘non-demand’ curve methods of estimating the value of environmental goods and services. Whereas economic valuation techniques attempt to derive recognised measures of economic value, such as consumer surplus or Hicksian measures of welfare, pricing approaches do not. As such they do not correspond with the notion of total economic value and measures of willingness to pay. Instead, these approaches provide a proxy of value by considering supply-side aspects. The following briefly summarises the basis of several different approaches (Bateman, 1999):
· Opportunity cost – this approach explicitly considers the value that it foregone in order to protect, enhance or create a particular environmental asset. For example, creation of a new forest implies the loss of land, typically for agricultural purposes. The opportunity cost of this action is then, the value (net of subsidies) of agricultural production foregone from land taken for the forest. Correspondingly, the value of the forest is at least equal to this opportunity cost.
· Cost of alternatives – is an approach which considers the cost of providing a substitute good which would provide a similar function to an environmental good. For example, wetlands which provide flood protection may be valued on the basis of the cost of building man-made flood defences of equal effectiveness. Given that flood protection is one of many wetland services, the value of the wetland is at least as much as the cost of the man-made protection that would be required in the absence of the wetland.
· Mitigation costs/avertive behaviour – this approach focuses on the price paid by individuals in order to mitigate against environmental impacts, in order to provide a basic monetary assessment of those impacts. For instance the cost of water filtration may be used as a proxy for the value of water pollution damages.
· Shadow project costs – is an approach which is concerned with the cost of providing and equal environmental good at an alternative location. Typically there are three potential scenarios: (i) asset reconstruction, which is the provision of an alternative site (e.g. a habitat); (ii) asset transplantation, which is moving the environmental feature, such as a habitat to a new site; and (iii) asset restoration, which entails enhancing an existing site that is currently degraded. The cost of the preferred option may then be applied as a minimum ‘price’ of the threatened environmental asset.
· Subsidy cost - an indication of the value of environmental goods may be inferred by considering the subsidies paid directly to producers for adopting production methods that are environmentally benign or beneficial. A common example would be subsidies paid to the agricultural sector for environmentally sensitive practices.
A1.1.1.4 Process of implementation
Primarily application of pricing approaches to valuing the environment relies on the use of price data observed from relevant markets. A procedure for implementing a pricing approach to value a specific environmental good or service can be envisaged as follows:
- Identify appropriate approach from which the value of the good may be inferred. This will likely depend on the environmental resource in question. As noted above, the opportunity cost approach can be used to estimate the value of forest preservation, where the alternative use of the land is readily identifiable (e.g. some form of agriculture). A proxy for the flood protection value of wetlands can be derived from cost of building equally effective man-made defences (e.g. the cost of alternatives approach), and so on.
- Identify the relevant good/market and collate data.
- Adjust price data so that it is net of tax or subsidy to derive the proxy value.
- Aggregate the proxy as appropriate (e.g. across affected population, etc).
A1.1.1.5 Data needs
Market data may be collected from secondary sources, or by primary collation. The availability of data may depend on the pricing approach which is adopted.
A1.1.1.6 Other practical issues for implementation
Since pricing approaches make use of observable market data and require little manipulation (i.e. adjust for price distortions) in order to derive proxies of value, the approach (subject to the actual collection of data) can likely be implemented in a relatively short-time frame.
A1.1.1.7 Principal outputs
As noted, the outputs of pricing approaches do not reflect measures of value as prescribed by economic theory. Principally, the proxy values derived will reflect the minimum value of environmental goods and services since they do not account for any excess of willingness to pay over price paid (e.g. consumer surplus).
A1.1.1.8 Transferability of outputs
The transferability of outputs from pricing approaches will likely depend on the extent of the market. For example the unit cost applied in the opportunity cost approach (e.g. the market price of a particular agricultural commodity) may vary according to location, hence it would be more appropriate to use the unit cost relevant to the area of interest.
A1.1.1.9 Key uses – decision-making context(s)
Use of market values is typically related to appraisal contexts, and as such may feed in to cost benefit analysis of projects. In practice, mitigation costs, or in the case of the EU Environmental Liability Directive, shadow project costs, may also be used as a minimum/lower bound basis for setting compensation or legal damage assessments, although note that these values do not typically reflect welfare losses that are incurred.
A1.1.1.10 Key uses – coverage of natural environment
The coverage of natural environment by pricing approaches will be dependent on the extent to which markets relevant to the environmental good or service in question exist. The following presents a number of practical examples. The opportunity cost approach is suited to assessing the creation or protection of environmental resources such as forests or tropical forest, which typically entails the loss of land for some productive use (typically agriculture). A number of studies have been applied in developing countries to assess the opportunity cost of protecting natural forests, see for example Kramer et al., (1994) who consider the opportunity cost borne by local villages as a result of loss of access to forest land resulting from the establishment of the Mantadia National Park, Madagascar. Other studies include Kremen et al., (2000) and Ruitenbeek (1992) who examine the foregone benefits from logging in relation to forest conservation. Costanza et al. (1989) provide an assessment of the economic value of coastal wetlands in Louisiana, where storm protection value is estimated on the basis of the cost of constructing equally effective man-made defences; an application of the cost of alternatives approach.
A1.1.1.11 Discussion
Market value approaches, as outlined above, typically only provide monetary proxies or ‘benchmarks’ against which the value of the environmental good in question can be judged. Values that may be derived from these approaches do not represent true valuations as the assessment only considers whether the environment good is of greater value than the opportunity cost (Bateman, 1999). Primarily, application of pricing rather than valuation methods risks the under-valuation of environmental goods. To expand, knowing the price of a good only informs on the cost of obtaining that good, rather than the actual benefit derived from the ‘consumption’ of the good. As suggested, the values derived from the opportunity cost, cost of alternatives, mitigation costs and shadow project costs are a benchmark set by the market. However, it is important to note that the use of subsidy costs will typically rely on what may be arbitrary values set by government which do not reflect opportunity cost.
With regards to opportunity costs, it is likely that the market price of output is likely to over-estimate the true opportunity cost of an action due distorted market structures which reflect the political objectives rather than competitive relationships. This may be particularly true when considering the agricultural sector. Highly intervened markets imply a certain degree of complexity in the link between market prices and underlying costs, suggesting that it may be difficult to assess the value of environmental goods in this manner.
Note also that mitigation costs will typically only provide a partial assessment of the environmental impact of interest. For instance, the cost of water filtration in order to improve water quality will only account for the impact that is experienced by water companies and their customers, and will not account for water pollution damages to aquatic ecosystems. In relation to the application of shadow project costs, an important aspect of the procedure would be to demonstrate the adequacy of the shadow project in terms of replicating the environmental function that is to be lost.
A1.1.1.12 Consideration of distributional impacts
Where markets are distorted, values observed in markets may actually reflect the preferences of government, who are essentially acting as a single arbiter of valuation, and/or particular interest groups, rather than the ‘true’ value of the environmental goods and services to society. This may result in insufficient weighting of values held by a significant number of individuals not represented by interest groups involved in the political process.
A1.1.1.13 Advantages and disadvantages
Generally, pricing approaches can be useful in providing an indicative monetary assessment of the value of environmental goods that might otherwise be regarded as ‘free’. In addition data may be readily attainable in the form of observable market prices, although some caution is needed in order to account for price distortions. Strictly though, use of market values which can inform on the price of obtaining a particular environmental good, does not inform on the value of the environmental good, and as such it is likely that pricing approach will lead to under-estimates of the ‘true’ value of environmental goods and services.
A1.1.1.14 Conflicts and synergies with other methods
Some aspects of pricing approaches, such as mitigation costs, may actually serve as inputs into the production function approach framework (PFA - see separate fiche). Note however, that in this context, these costs are an input to the analysis in that they are likely to alter production or cost functions. The PFA enables estimates of changes in consumer and producer surpluses to be estimated as a result of changes in the provision of environmental goods and services which are inputs to production processes (e.g. water quality).