Contracts: Table of Contents
I. Contract Remedies
A. When K Involves a Doctor’s Promises (Ponzetti’s Promise 45.0)
B. When K Involves Economic Waste & Land (Lap Pool 46.0)
C. When parties will negotiate around it anyway (Coase Theorem)
D. When Equitable Relief is Appropriate (Gabby Hayes 47.0)
E. When You Want More Than “Run of the Mill” Loss (Spare the Rod 53.0)
F. When Restitution is a Better Choice (A Slippery Path 50.0)
G. When Reliance is a Better Choice (Durin’s Bain 49.0)
H. When Liquidated Damages are Valid (Grand Trip 48.0)
I. When Damages are Too Speculative (Top Cream 52.0)
J. When a Warranty Presents Special Risk ($17.60 54.0)
K. When Failure to [take incentive to] Mitigate Reduces Award (Pippin’s Place 55.0)
II. Consideration
A. Consideration vs. Gift Promises (“B” is for Beresford 3.0)
C. Past Consideration (Estate of Vernon Gagne I 4.0)
D. Promissory Estoppel (Estate of Vernon Gagne II 5.0)
III. Offer and Acceptance
A. Importance of Offer & Acceptance (How Much for that Houseboat 7.0)
B. Offer
1. Bilateral Contracts
2. Unilateral Contracts
3. Counteroffer
C. Revocation
D. Acceptance
E. Battle of the Forms (Clockwork Fabrications 12.0)
F. Indefiniteness (Emmanuel p. 61)
G. Modification (Emanuel p. 125,482)
IV. Regulation of the Bargaining Process
A. Statute of Frauds (The Birthas 18.0)
B. Parol Evidence Rule & Construction (Humphrey’s Bonus 28.0)
C. Interpretation (A Retired Cowboy with Nothing Better to do 30.0)
D. Unconscionability (Scuba Accident 24.0)
1. Secured Loans
2. Personal Injury Releases
3. Arbitration Clauses (Justice by Any Other Name 27.0)
4. Surrogates (Here’s Danny 16.1)
5. Capacity (Cooked Pudding 19.0)
6. Duress
7. Fraud (Keanne SAAB 22.0)
V. Performance Standards
A. Nondisclosure (A Fisher of Sorts 23.0)
B. Promise & Condition (The Bonus 31.0, Shooting a Database 32.0)
C. Express vs. Constructive Conditions
D. Mistake (Detroit Lions 36.0)
E. Impossibility, Impracticability, and Frustration of Purpose
1. Impossibility and Impracticality (Agate Dog 37.0 & Alvert’s Pool 39.0)
2. Frustration of Purpose (The Problem with Bones 40.0)
VI. Breach
A. Anticipatory Repudiation: Common Law (Sherman Trainer I 41.0)
B. Anticipatory Repudiation: UCC (Sherman Trainer II 42.0)
VII. Warranties
A. Types of Warranties
B. Breach of Warranty
C. Remedies
D. Privity
VIII. Sales Contracts
A. Buyer’s Remedies
1. Cover (Go Blue 56.0)
2. Self-Cover (VisualBooks 57.1)
3. Risk Shifting Insurance Contracts (57.2)
B. Seller’s Remedies
1. Accepting/Rejecting (The Thinge 58.0)
2. Lost Volume (Power Pod 59.0)
IX. Third Parties & Assignments
A. Vocabulary (Burnham 202-212)
B. Third Party Beneficiaries (A Man’s Word 60.0)
C. The Meaning of Intent…in Iowa (A Chewer 61.0)
D. Unjust Enrichment (Gitchee Gummie Mosiquitoes 62.0)
Contracts Outline
Content of Course6 Questions
- What law applies?
- Was there a K?
- What were the terms of K?
- Did someone breach?
- Is the breach excused?
- If not, what damages?
I. Contract Remedies
Standard: When dealing with a breach of contract, the general rule is that you award expectation damagesunless there is a good reason not to treat it like a commercial contract.
The following are exceptions to this general rule…
A. When K Involves a Doctor’s Promises (Ponzetti’s Promise 45.0)
Standard: There is something about medicine (the lack of precision, different interpretations of doctor’s promises) that makes us hesitant about treating medical contracts like commercial contracts.
Exception: When there is a specific promise, inducement (Hawkins)
Sullivan v. ‘Connor (1973)
An entertainer had a nose job and she became horribly disfigured; won on med mal charge put lost on contracts issue
Are medical contracts enforceable? Goldilocks expectancy is too high, restitution is too low, reliance is “just right
Hawkins v. McGree Medical case where expectation damages were awarded
Boy had skin graft on scarred hand from skin on chest; he ended up with a hairy hand
Should damages give him back the scarred hand or the perfect hand he was promised? The court said the perfect hand because there was a specific promise and inducement from doctor
Zehr v. Haugen (1994)
Mother underwent tubal ligation and became pregnant afterwards
Can she sue for cost of pregnancy and future costs of child? Court concludes that claim is not too speculative because consequences are reasonably foreseeable
Singelton v. Stegall (1991)
Man in jail sues attorney for failing to file papers in time to get him “his day in court” The court allows claim, but limits his recovery to damages separate from those proximately flowing from his encounter with legal process
B. When K Involves Economic Waste & Land (Lap Pool 46.0)
There is something special/different about a person’s land
Standard: If cost to repair is greater than total value of property, then it causes unreasonable economics waste (not material to breach)
Exception: If owners will really pay anything to get what they want; they will use the money awarded to rebuild
Willie’s Construction Co. v. Baker (1992)
wanted 100 in. basement walls, but only gave them the standard 80 in.; Courts awards cost to repair (tear down house) reasoning that it is better to overcompensate wronged party that worry about overcompensation
Hancock v. Northcutt (1991)
’s earthen pod home has severe problem in Pod #7; fear of collapse; was awarded nearly three times the value of the house; Court ruled that instruction to award cost of repair (and break rule) must include requirement that will rebuild
C. When parties will negotiate around it anyway (Coase Theorem)
Coase Theorem and Principle of Efficient Breach
- Coase Theorem—in a world where there are no transaction costs, the legal rule is irrelevant; the same mix of goods and services in society will always exist because bargaining will always yield the same result; goal is to maximize the benefit to society
- Principle of Efficient Breach—rebuttal to argument that contract breaching is immoral abd it is should be punished severely
Economics suggests that it is a good thing that services do not always go to the first person (widget example)
We don’t want to overdeter contract beach because sometimes breach is actually a good thingBut what’s wrong with this?
- Litigation is not costless
- Most people won’t sue if you have a modest breach; our legal system does not function perfectly (we deter criminals)
The rule in contacts is not about deterrence; it is about expectation damages. It is better to allow some evil people to take advantage of this, than to deter efficient breach
D. When Equitable Relief is Appropriate (Gabby Hayes 47.0)
Equitable Remedies / Legal Remedies- Specific performance
- Injunction
- Awarded when damages are too speculative or there is no substitute for ’s performance
- Money Damages
- Usual remedy for contract breach
- 3 kinds: expectation, reliance, restitution
Standard: Courts generally do not order specific performance
Exception: 3 pre-conditions to granting equitable relief:
- Money damages must be inadequate
- Contract terms must be definite
- Court’s task of enforcing/supervising must not be unduly difficult
Pingley v. Brunson (1979)
Organist and restaurant owner made a contract and organist stopped showing up
Can get specific performance? The court said no because the remedy was in law; there were other organists available of equal ability to do the job
Cahill v. Board of Education (1982)
Biology teacher left job and became trained in library science; got job offers from other schools; filed suit because failed to employ her in library science; Court would not allow injunction because they believed that received adequate remedy at law
Clark v. Pennsylvania State Police (1981)
Policeman got promise that he would be promoted to Captain if he received legal training; he went to law school, but his request for a promotion was denied; Court would not order specific performance because it was not shown that money was inadequate
E. When You Want More Than “Run of the Mill” Loss (Spare the Rod 53.0)
Hadley v. Baxendale (1854) “The Pennoyer v. Neff of Contracts”
operated a mill, which suspended operation because of a broken crank shaft; carrier negligently delayed delivery of shaft and the mill suffered great economic loss due to closure; knew that shaft was for mill, but was not told that mill was closed because of shaft
Are economic damages too unforeseeable for recovery? Court did not allow recovery of lost profits
Standard:Hadley v. Baxendale Rule The general rule is that you get “run of the mill” damages (what the average person would suffer) unless…
Exception:
- The damages arise naturally from the breach itself
- The damages arise from special circumstances that were communicated by the to the , and accepts the risk
Starmakers Publishing Corp v. Acme Fast Freight Inc. (1985)
Starmakers entered contract with Acme for delivery of printed matter; the delivery was late and Starmaker’s lost a valuable customer; Because Acme did not have actual notice, the court enforced Hadley and refused special damages
Affiliated Foods Inc. v. Puerto Rico Marine Management Co. (1986)
was supposed to deliver produce to cruise ship, but when truck opened, there was only cheese; had to pay for alternate transportation of fruit
Are ’s liable for cost of alterative transport because any idiot would know that failure to deliver fruit to cruise ship would annoy people? Court rules for because they are reluctant to hold people to pay big damages if it was not crystal clear that they knew about it
F. When Restitution is a Better Choice (A Slippery Path 50.0)
Standard:Restitution is mainly used when…
- A non-breaching has partly performed
- A breaching has not substantially performed (Brtitton v. Turner)
*Often used for quasi-contract action
**In some jurisdictions, restitution is limited by contract price
Lee v. Foote (1984) situation 1
was supposed to do carpentry and was supposed to do plumbing; did some carpentry, but never started plumbing so sued; court first said that correct award was cost to hire other plumbers; then they said was entitled to the reasonable value of his carpentry
Constantino v. American S/T Achilles (1978) situation1
cleaned 24/33 storage tanks and ordered them to leave
Does contract price put a limit on recovery? Court says no although some think that should not get more by being ordered to leave than if he would have finished
Britton v. Turner (1834) situation 2
was supposed to work for one year, but he left for no reason after 9 months; court says that is entitled to recover what his work was reasonably worth because of a general understanding that people should be paid for what they do; even breaching party can be entitled to restitution
Jaeger v. Slovak American Charitable Association (1987)
Jaeger (, general contractor) ceased work on building and sued association for breach of construction contract; association eventually sold the property for a lot of money;
Were windows the only benefit? Rule = after partial performance, defaulting builder can recover benefit received from non-breaching party; evidence shows that partial performance conferred no benefit on the association therefore, award is affirmed
G. When Reliance is a Better Choice (Durin’s Bain 49.0)
Standard: Reliance is mainly used when…
- It is impossible to measure the ’s expectation interest accurately
- The recovers on promissory estoppel (additional reasonable losses)
*Where do you draw the line with reliance?
L. Albert & Son v. Amrstrong Rubber Co. (1949)
Buyer ordered 4 refiners and got 2 then 2; he refused to accept; seller sued for value of equipment to prepare; this is a case where they made a losing deal, and if contract had been performed they would have lost money you don’t want expectation damages; court said “sorry, you can’t play that game; if you made a losing deal, you made a losing deal”
Bausch & Lomb v. Bressler (1992)
Medical sales contract violated; agreement included down payment; breaching party sued and non-breaching party got down payment back as a restitution award
H. When Liquidated Damages are Valid (Grand Trip 48.0)
Standard: A liquidated damage clause is valid when it meets 1 (sometimes 2) of the following requirements:
- The amount is reasonable relative to actual loss from breach
- Harm caused by breach must be uncertain or very difficult to calculate
*A LD clause is not valid when it is a penalty (why? Penalties fail to promote efficient breach & are oppressive) and when it is not a reasonable damages of what damages would be
Vines v. Orchard Hills, Inc. (1980)
Home purchasers paid 10% down, but could not purchase because of job transfer; court allowed to have day in court to prove that LD clause should not be enforced; factors include willfulness (Dean R has issue with this) of breach and accuracy in relation to actual damages (house increased in value)
Mason v. Fakhimi (1993)
won 6 units in auction, but stopped payment to check because Nellis base was closing; court said that LD clause was not enforceable because actual damages were 1/3 predicted damages
Lake River Corp. v. Caborundum Co. (1985)
C made powder and LR was to provide distribution services; LR installed new bagging system on C’s request; contract included a minimum quantity guarantee; C failed to meet this amount; LR stopped shipping and C had a third party ship remainder; contract provided liquidated damages difference between quantity bagged and quantity guaranteed
Does the formula in minimum guarantee clause impose a penalty or is it a valid liquidated damages clause? This is a penalty because it is designed to always give Lake River more than its actual damages
I. When Damages are Too Speculative (Top Cream 52.0)
Standard: can only recover for losses, which he establishes with “reasonable certainty”
Nominal damages breach is recognized, but no consequential damages ($)
Freund v. Washington Square Press (1974)
had publishing deal with company, but they ended up not publishing his book; court said no to specific performance; should he get nominal damages or more? He should get nominal damages because the court does not want him to come out better than if contract were performed
Contemporary Mission Inc. v. Famous Music Corp. (1977)
Christian priests wrote “Virgin” and sold it to Famous with agreement to create Crunch record label; promise was broken and sued; statistical evidence of damage was presented; court awarded almost entire judgment to P; if damages are certain, but amount is not certain then should not be denied
J. When a Warranty Presents Special Risk ($17.60 54.0)
Two types of warranties…
- Express: things seller is telling you about product to get you to buy it, advertised
- Implied: seller does not directly giving them; they arise from contracts (everything has implied warranty of merchantability according to UCC)
Rule: There is only 1 way to get ride of the warranty of merchantability; the disclaimer must use the word merchantability and it must be explicit (can’t be in small print)
What to know Contract price can be an indicator of special risk
Vitol Trading v. SGS Control Services (1988)
Vitol contracted SGS to test their crude to determine if it was “poor” and SGS guaranteed accuracy; testing was inaccurate and Vitol had to sell poor crude at a loss; court said that SGS breached a duty to perform in a workman-like manner, but the breach did not cause harm (the crude was poor regardless); this is the theory that “you can’t shoot the messenger”
Sundance Cruises Corp. v. ABS (1993)
Sundance hired ABS to inspect ship and ABS approved; ship sank because of two holes and valve problem not reported by ABS; Sundance sought $264M even though contract was ony $85K; court gave summary judgment to ABS because small fee was not intended to protect against large damage
Perini Corp. V. Greate Bay Hotel & Casino (Sands) (1992)
Sands bought Brighton Hotel and entered into casino renovation contract with Perini; Sand terminated contract because Perini was not performing on time; lower court awarded Sands lost profits, contract balances, etc. Was it wrong to award more than Perini’s fee? Court says that Perini was aware of its exposure to liability for lost profits at time of contracting so disproportionate award is OK
International Ore & Fertilizer Corp. v. SGS Control Services (1994)
Interore hired SGS to inspect shipment of fertilizers; SGS negligently represented cleanliness of cargo; court dismissed contract claim because of low contract price and informal dealings; appellate court believes that SGS owes full damages because this was not a one-time hiring; they knew the risks of business; however, appellate court could not change monetary award?
K. When Failure to [take incentive to] Mitigate Reduces Award (Pippin’s Place 55.0)
Standard: Reasonableness if could have avoided an item of damages by a reasonable effort, he may not recover for that item if he fails to make effort
Parker v. 20th Century Fox (1970)
Shirley McLaine () was offered part in “Bloomer,” but company decided not to produce movie; they offered her a part in “Big Country” instead
Should her damages be reduced because she did not take the part? No, because the parts were not equal; other employment must be comparable and similar (this can be tricky)
O’Brien v. Black (1994)
Tenant () had 5 year lease, but he left; landlord did not seek another tenant, but he sued for damages from the moment moved out until someone new moved in (waited for a national chain store that would pay high rent)
Should his damages be reduced because of failure to mitigate? Landlord cannot impose cost of decision on tenant; issue is not whether or not it was a sound business decision, but whether can charge abandoning with risk
II. Consideration
Standard: (R2d 71-81) Consideration is required to make an agreement enforceable. Consideration must be sufficient (value) & adequate (how much). A promise is supported by consideration if 2 requirements are met
- The promisee gave up something of value (legal detriment)
- The promisor made his promise as part of a bargain, or in exchange for something
Exception:Promissory Estoppel (R 2d 81-95) Doctrine designed to enforce promises that are not supported by consideration, but induce the detrimental reliance by the promisee